Financial economics is the branch of economics characterized by a "concentration on monetary activities", in which "money of one type or another is likely to appear on both sides of a trade".[1]
Its concern is thus the interrelation of financial variables, such as share prices, interest rates and exchange rates, as opposed to those concerning the real economy.
It has two main areas of focus:[2]asset pricing and corporate finance; the first being the perspective of providers of capital, i.e. investors, and the second of users of capital.
It thus provides the theoretical underpinning for much of finance.
The subject is concerned with "the allocation and deployment of economic resources, both spatially and across time, in an uncertain environment".[3][4] It therefore centers on decision making under uncertainty in the context of the financial markets, and the resultant economic and financial models and principles, and is concerned with deriving testable or policy implications from acceptable assumptions.
It thus also includes a formal study of the financial markets themselves, especially market microstructure and market regulation.
It is built on the foundations of microeconomics and decision theory.
Financial econometrics is the branch of financial economics that uses econometric techniques to parameterise the relationships identified.
Mathematical finance is related in that it will derive and extend the mathematical or numerical models suggested by financial economics.
Whereas financial economics has a primarily microeconomic focus, monetary economics is primarily macroeconomic in nature.
Calculating their present value, in the first formula, allows the decision maker to aggregate the cashflows (or other returns) to be produced by the asset in the future to a single value at the date in question, and to thus more readily compare two opportunities; this concept is then the starting point for financial decision making.
[note 1]
(Note that here, "" represents a generic (or arbitrary) discount rate applied to the cash flows, whereas in the valuation formulae, the risk-free rate is applied once these have been "adjusted" for their riskiness; see below.)
An immediate extension is to combine probabilities with present value, leading to the expected value criterion which sets asset value as a function of the sizes of the expected payouts and the probabilities of their occurrence, and respectively. [note 2]
This decision method, however, fails to consider risk aversion. In other words, since individuals receive greater utility from an extra dollar when they are poor and less utility when comparatively rich, the approach is therefore to "adjust" the weight assigned to the various outcomes, i.e. "states", correspondingly: . See indifference price. (Some investors may in fact be risk seeking as opposed to risk averse, but the same logic would apply.)
Choice under uncertainty here may then be defined as the maximization of expected utility. More formally, the resulting expected utility hypothesis states that, if certain axioms are satisfied, the subjective value associated with a gamble by an individual is that individual's statistical expectation of the valuations of the outcomes of that gamble.
The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics (2008, 2nd ed.) also uses the JEL codes to classify its entries in v. 8, Subject Index, including Financial Economics at pp. 863–64. The below have links to entry abstracts of The New Palgrave Online for each primary or secondary JEL category (10 or fewer per page, similar to Google searches):
Tertiary category entries can also be searched.[10]
The concepts of arbitrage-free, "rational", pricing and equilibrium are then coupled
[11]
with the above to derive various of the "classical"[12] (or "neo-classical"[13]) financial economics models.
Rational pricing is the assumption that asset prices (and hence asset pricing models) will reflect the arbitrage-free price of the asset, as any deviation from this price will be "arbitraged away". This assumption is useful in pricing fixed income securities, particularly bonds, and is fundamental to the pricing of derivative instruments.
Economic equilibrium is a state in which economic forces such as supply and demand are balanced, and in the absence of external influences these equilibrium values of economic variables will not change. General equilibrium deals with the behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that a set of prices exists that will result in an overall equilibrium. (This is in contrast to partial equilibrium, which only analyzes single markets.)
The two concepts are linked as follows: where market prices do not allow profitable arbitrage, i.e. they comprise an arbitrage-free market, then these prices are also said to constitute an "arbitrage equilibrium". Intuitively, this may be seen by considering that where an arbitrage opportunity does exist, then prices can be expected to change, and they are therefore not in equilibrium.[14] An arbitrage equilibrium is thus a precondition for a general economic equilibrium.
"Complete" here means that there is a price for every asset in every possible state of the world, , and that the complete set of possible bets on future states-of-the-world can therefore be constructed with existing assets (assuming no friction): essentially solving simultaneously for n (risk-neutral) probabilities, , given n prices. For a simplified example see Rational pricing § Risk neutral valuation, where the economy has only two possible states – up and down – and where and (=) are the two corresponding probabilities, and in turn, the derived distribution, or "measure".
The formal derivation will proceed by arbitrage arguments.[6][14][11]The analysis here is often undertaken assuming a representative agent,[15] essentially treating all market participants, "agents", as identical (or, at least, assuming that they act in such a way that the sum of their choices is equivalent to the decision of one individual) with the effect that the problems are then mathematically tractable.
With this measure in place, the expected, i.e. required, return of any security (or portfolio) will then equal the risk-free return, plus an "adjustment for risk",[6] i.e. a security-specific risk premium, compensating for the extent to which its cashflows are unpredictable. All pricing models are then essentially variants of this, given specific assumptions or conditions.[6][5][16] This approach is consistent with the above, but with the expectation based on "the market" (i.e. arbitrage-free, and, per the theorem, therefore in equilibrium) as opposed to individual preferences.
Continuing the example, in pricing a derivative instrument, its forecasted cashflows in the above-mentioned up- and down-states and , are multiplied through by and , and are then discounted at the risk-free interest rate; per the second equation above. In pricing a "fundamental", underlying, instrument (in equilibrium), on the other hand, a risk-appropriate premium over risk-free is required in the discounting, essentially employing the first equation with and combined. This premium may be derived by the CAPM (or extensions) as will be seen under § Uncertainty.
The difference is explained as follows: By construction, the value of the derivative will (must) grow at the risk free rate, and, by arbitrage arguments, its value must then be discounted correspondingly; in the case of an option, this is achieved by "manufacturing" the instrument as a combination of the underlying and a risk free "bond"; see Rational pricing § Delta hedging (and § Uncertainty below). Where the underlying is itself being priced, such "manufacturing" is of course not possible – the instrument being "fundamental", i.e. as opposed to "derivative" – and a premium is then required for risk.
(Correspondingly, mathematical finance separates into two analytic regimes:
risk and portfolio management (generally) use physical (or actual or actuarial) probability, denoted by "P"; while derivatives pricing uses risk-neutral probability (or arbitrage-pricing probability), denoted by "Q".
In specific applications the lower case is used, as in the above equations.)
State prices
With the above relationship established, the further specialized Arrow–Debreu model may be derived.
[note 4]
This result suggests that, under certain economic conditions, there must be a set of prices such that aggregate supplies will equal aggregate demands for every commodity in the economy.
The Arrow–Debreu model applies to economies with maximally complete markets, in which there exists a market for every time period and forward prices for every commodity at all time periods.
A direct extension, then, is the concept of a state price security, also called an Arrow–Debreu security, a contract that agrees to pay one unit of a numeraire (a currency or a commodity) if a particular state occurs ("up" and "down" in the simplified example above) at a particular time in the future and pays zero numeraire in all the other states. The price of this security is the state price of this particular state of the world; also referred to as a "Risk Neutral Density".[20]
In the above example, the state prices, , would equate to the present values of and : i.e. what one would pay today, respectively, for the up- and down-state securities; the state price vector is the vector of state prices for all states. Applied to derivative valuation, the price today would simply be [× + ×]: the fourth formula (see above regarding the absence of a risk premium here). For a continuous random variable indicating a continuum of possible states, the value is found by integrating over the state price "density".
State prices find immediate application as a conceptual tool ("contingent claim analysis");[6] but can also be applied to valuation problems.[21] Given the pricing mechanism described, one can decompose the derivative value – true in fact for "every security"[2] – as a linear combination of its state-prices; i.e. back-solve for the state-prices corresponding to observed derivative prices.[22][21][20]
These recovered state-prices can then be used for valuation of other instruments with exposure to the underlyer, or for other decision making relating to the underlyer itself.
Using the related stochastic discount factor - also called the pricing kernel - the asset price is computed by "discounting" the future cash flow by the stochastic factor , and then taking the expectation;[16]
the third equation above. Essentially, this factor divides expected utility at the relevant future period - a function of the possible asset values realized under each state - by the utility due to today's wealth, and is then also referred to as "the intertemporal marginal rate of substitution".
Resultant models
Bond valuation formula where Coupons and Face value are discounted at the appropriate rate, "i": typically a spread over the (per period) risk free rate as a function of credit risk; often quoted as a "yield to maturity". See body for discussion re the relationship with the above pricing formulae.
The expected return used when discounting cashflows on an asset , is the risk-free rate plus the market premium multiplied by beta (), the asset's correlated volatility relative to the overall market .
Interpretation: by arbitrage arguments, the instantaneous impact of time and change in spot price on an option price will (must) realize as growth at , the risk free rate, when the option is correctly "manufactured".
Interpretation: The value of a call is the risk free rated present value of its expected in the money value - i.e. a specific formulation of the fundamental valuation result. is the probability that the call will be exercised; is the present value of the expected asset price at expiration, given that the asset price at expiration is above the exercise price.
Applying the above economic concepts, we may then derive various economic- and financial models and principles. As above, the two usual areas of focus are Asset Pricing and Corporate Finance, the first being the perspective of providers of capital, the second of users of capital. Here, and for (almost) all other financial economics models, the questions addressed are typically framed in terms of "time, uncertainty, options, and information",[1][15] as will be seen below.
Time: money now is traded for money in the future.
Uncertainty (or risk): The amount of money to be transferred in the future is uncertain.
Options: one party to the transaction can make a decision at a later time that will affect subsequent transfers of money.
Information: knowledge of the future can reduce, or possibly eliminate, the uncertainty associated with future monetary value (FMV).
Applying this framework, with the above concepts, leads to the required models. This derivation begins with the assumption of "no uncertainty" and is then expanded to incorporate the other considerations.[4] (This division sometimes denoted "deterministic" and "random",[23] or "stochastic".)
Certainty
The starting point here is "Investment under certainty", and usually framed in the context of a corporation.
The Fisher separation theorem, asserts that the objective of the corporation will be the maximization of its present value, regardless of the preferences of its shareholders.
Related is the Modigliani–Miller theorem, which shows that, under certain conditions, the value of a firm is unaffected by how that firm is financed, and depends neither on its dividend policy nor its decision to raise capital by issuing stock or selling debt. The proof here proceeds using arbitrage arguments, and acts as a benchmark [11] for evaluating the effects of factors outside the model that do affect value.
[note 5]
The mechanism for determining (corporate) value is provided by
[26][27]John Burr Williams' The Theory of Investment Value, which proposes that the value of an asset should be calculated using "evaluation by the rule of present worth". Thus, for a common stock, the "intrinsic", long-term worth is the present value of its future net cashflows, in the form of dividends. What remains to be determined is the appropriate discount rate. Later developments show that, "rationally", i.e. in the formal sense, the appropriate discount rate here will (should) depend on the asset's riskiness relative to the overall market, as opposed to its owners' preferences; see below. Net present value (NPV) is the direct extension of these ideas typically applied to Corporate Finance decisioning. For other results, as well as specific models developed here, see the list of "Equity valuation" topics under Outline of finance § Discounted cash flow valuation.
[note 6]
Bond valuation, in that cashflows (coupons and return of principal, or "Face value") are deterministic, may proceed in the same fashion.[23] An immediate extension, Arbitrage-free bond pricing, discounts each cashflow at the market derived rate – i.e. at each coupon's corresponding zero rate, and of equivalent credit worthiness – as opposed to an overall rate.
In many treatments bond valuation precedes equity valuation, under which cashflows (dividends) are not "known" per se. Williams and onward allow for forecasting as to these – based on historic ratios or published dividend policy – and cashflows are then treated as essentially deterministic; see below under § Corporate finance theory.
For both stocks and bonds, "under certainty, with the focus on cash flows from securities over time," valuation based on a term structure of interest rates is in fact consistent with arbitrage-free pricing.[28]
Indeed, a corollary of the above is that "the law of one price implies the existence of a discount factor"; [29]
correspondingly, as formulated, .
Whereas these "certainty" results are all commonly employed under corporate finance, uncertainty is the focus of "asset pricing models" as follows. Fisher's formulation of the theory here - developing an intertemporal equilibrium model - underpins also [26] the below applications to uncertainty;
[note 7]
see [30] for the development.
Briefly, and intuitively – and consistent with § Arbitrage-free pricing and equilibrium above – the relationship between rationality and efficiency is as follows.[31]
Given the ability to profit from private information, self-interested traders are motivated to acquire and act on their private information. In doing so, traders contribute to more and more "correct", i.e. efficient, prices: the efficient-market hypothesis, or EMH. Thus, if prices of financial assets are (broadly) efficient, then deviations from these (equilibrium) values could not last for long. (See earnings response coefficient.)
The EMH (implicitly) assumes that average expectations constitute an "optimal forecast", i.e. prices using all available information are identical to the best guess of the future: the assumption of rational expectations.
The EMH does allow that when faced with new information, some investors may overreact and some may underreact,
[32]
but what is required, however, is that investors' reactions follow a normal distribution – so that the net effect on market prices cannot be reliably exploited [32] to make an abnormal profit.
In the competitive limit, then, market prices will reflect all available information and prices can only move in response to news: [33] the random walk hypothesis.
This news, of course, could be "good" or "bad", minor or, less common, major; and these moves are then, correspondingly, normally distributed; with the price therefore following a log-normal distribution.
[note 8]
Under these conditions, investors can then be assumed to act rationally: their investment decision must be calculated or a loss is sure to follow; [32] correspondingly, where an arbitrage opportunity presents itself, then arbitrageurs will exploit it, reinforcing this equilibrium.
Here, as under the certainty-case above, the specific assumption as to pricing is that prices are calculated as the present value of expected future dividends,
[5][33][15]
as based on currently available information.
What is required though, is a theory for determining the appropriate discount rate, i.e. "required return", given this uncertainty: this is provided by the MPT and its CAPM. Relatedly, rationality – in the sense of arbitrage-exploitation – gives rise to Black–Scholes; option values here ultimately consistent with the CAPM.
In general, then, while portfolio theory studies how investors should balance risk and return when investing in many assets or securities, the CAPM is more focused, describing how, in equilibrium, markets set the prices of assets in relation to how risky they are.
[note 9]
This result will be independent of the investor's level of risk aversion and assumed utility function, thus providing a readily determined discount rate for corporate finance decision makers as above,[36] and for other investors.
The argument proceeds as follows:
[37]
If one can construct an efficient frontier – i.e. each combination of assets offering the best possible expected level of return for its level of risk, see diagram – then mean-variance efficient portfolios can be formed simply as a combination of holdings of the risk-free asset and the "market portfolio" (the Mutual fund separation theorem), with the combinations here plotting as the capital market line, or CML.
Then, given this CML, the required return on a risky security will be independent of the investor's utility function, and solely determined by its covariance ("beta") with aggregate, i.e. market, risk.
This is because investors here can then maximize utility through leverage as opposed to pricing; see Separation property (finance), Markowitz model § Choosing the best portfolio and CML diagram aside.
As can be seen in the formula aside, this result is consistent with the preceding, equaling the riskless return plus an adjustment for risk.[5]
A more modern, direct, derivation is as described at the bottom of this section; which can be generalized to derive other equilibrium-pricing models.
Black–Scholes provides a mathematical model of a financial market containing derivative instruments, and the resultant formula for the price of European-styled options.
[note 10]
The model is expressed as the Black–Scholes equation, a partial differential equation describing the changing price of the option over time; it is derived assuming log-normal, geometric Brownian motion (see Brownian model of financial markets).
The key financial insight behind the model is that one can perfectly hedge the option by buying and selling the underlying asset in just the right way and consequently "eliminate risk", absenting the risk adjustment from the pricing (, the value, or price, of the option, grows at , the risk-free rate).[6][5]
This hedge, in turn, implies that there is only one right price – in an arbitrage-free sense – for the option. And this price is returned by the Black–Scholes option pricing formula. (The formula, and hence the price, is consistent with the equation, as the formula is the solution to the equation.)
Since the formula is without reference to the share's expected return, Black–Scholes inheres risk neutrality; intuitively consistent with the "elimination of risk" here, and mathematically consistent with § Arbitrage-free pricing and equilibrium above. Relatedly, therefore, the pricing formula may also be derived directly via risk neutral expectation.
Itô's lemma provides the underlying mathematics, and, with Itô calculus more generally, remains fundamental in quantitative finance.
[note 11]
As implied by the Fundamental Theorem, the two major results are consistent.
Here, the Black Scholes equation can alternatively be derived from the CAPM, and the price obtained from the Black–Scholes model is thus consistent with the assumptions of the CAPM.[45][13]
The Black–Scholes theory, although built on Arbitrage-free pricing, is therefore consistent with the equilibrium based capital asset pricing.
Both models, in turn, are ultimately consistent with the Arrow–Debreu theory, and can be derived via state-pricing – essentially, by expanding the fundamental result above – further explaining, and if required demonstrating, this consistency. [6]
Here, the CAPM is derived by linking , risk aversion, to overall market return, and setting the return on security as ; see Stochastic discount factor § Properties.
The Black–Scholes formula is found, in the limit, by attaching a binomial probability[11] to each of numerous possible spot-prices (i.e. states) and then rearranging for the terms corresponding to and , per the boxed description; see Binomial options pricing model § Relationship with Black–Scholes.
Extensions
More recent work further generalizes and extends these models. As regards asset pricing, developments in equilibrium-based pricing are discussed under "Portfolio theory" below, while "Derivative pricing" relates to risk-neutral, i.e. arbitrage-free, pricing. As regards the use of capital, "Corporate finance theory" relates, mainly, to the application of these models.
Whereas the above extend the CAPM, the single-index model is a more simple model. It assumes, only, a correlation between security and market returns, without (numerous) other economic assumptions. It is useful in that it simplifies the estimation of correlation between securities, significantly reducing the inputs for building the correlation matrix required for portfolio optimization. The arbitrage pricing theory (APT) similarly differs as regards its assumptions. APT "gives up the notion that there is one right portfolio for everyone in the world, and ...replaces it with an explanatory model of what drives asset returns."[46] It returns the required (expected) return of a financial asset as a linear function of various macro-economic factors, and assumes that arbitrage should bring incorrectly priced assets back into line.[note 12]
The linear factor model structure of the APT is used as the basis for many of the commercial risk systems employed by asset managers.
Interpretation: Analogous to Black–Scholes,
[51]
arbitrage arguments describe the instantaneous change in the bond price for changes in the (risk-free) short rate ; the analyst selects the specific short-rate model to be employed.
Drawing on these techniques, models for various other underlyings and applications have also been developed, all based on the same logic (using "contingent claim analysis"). Real options valuation allows that option holders can influence the option's underlying; models for employee stock option valuation explicitly assume non-rationality on the part of option holders; Credit derivatives allow that payment obligations or delivery requirements might not be honored. Exotic derivatives are now routinely valued. Multi-asset underlyers are handled via simulation or copula based analysis.
Following the Crash of 1987, equity options traded in American markets began to exhibit what is known as a "volatility smile"; that is, for a given expiration, options whose strike price differs substantially from the underlying asset's price command higher prices, and thus implied volatilities, than what is suggested by BSM. (The pattern differs across various markets.) Modelling the volatility smile is an active area of research, and developments here – as well as implications re the standard theory – are discussed in the next section.
After the 2007–2008 financial crisis, a further development:[60] as outlined, (over the counter) derivative pricing had relied on the BSM risk neutral pricing framework, under the assumptions of funding at the risk free rate and the ability to perfectly replicate cashflows so as to fully hedge. This, in turn, is built on the assumption of a credit-risk-free environment – called into question during the crisis.
Addressing this, therefore, issues such as counterparty credit risk, funding costs and costs of capital are now additionally considered when pricing,[61] and a credit valuation adjustment, or CVA – and potentially other valuation adjustments, collectively xVA – is generally added to the risk-neutral derivative value.
The standard economic arguments can be extended to incorporate these various adjustments.[62]
A related, and perhaps more fundamental change, is that discounting is now on the Overnight Index Swap (OIS) curve, as opposed to LIBOR as used previously.[60] This is because post-crisis, the overnight rate is considered a better proxy for the "risk-free rate".[63] (Also, practically, the interest paid on cash collateral is usually the overnight rate; OIS discounting is then, sometimes, referred to as "CSA discounting".) Swap pricing – and, therefore, yield curve construction – is further modified: previously, swaps were valued off a single "self discounting" interest rate curve; whereas post crisis, to accommodate OIS discounting, valuation is now under a "multi-curve framework" where "forecast curves" are constructed for each floating-leg LIBOR tenor, with discounting on the common OIS curve.
Mirroring the above developments, corporate finance valuations and decisioning no longer need assume "certainty".
Monte Carlo methods in finance allow financial analysts to construct "stochastic" or probabilistic corporate finance models, as opposed to the traditional static and deterministic models;[64] see Corporate finance § Quantifying uncertainty.
Relatedly, Real Options theory allows for owner – i.e. managerial – actions that impact underlying value: by incorporating option pricing logic, these actions are then applied to a distribution of future outcomes, changing with time, which then determine the "project's" valuation today.[65]
More traditionally, decision trees – which are complementary – have been used to evaluate projects, by incorporating in the valuation (all) possible events (or states) and consequent management decisions;[66][64] the correct discount rate here reflecting each decision-point's "non-diversifiable risk looking forward."[64][note 16]
Related to this, is the treatment of forecasted cashflows in equity valuation. In many cases, following Williams above, the average (or most likely) cash-flows were discounted,[68] as opposed to a theoretically correct state-by-state treatment under uncertainty; see comments under Financial modeling § Accounting.
In more modern treatments, then, it is the expected cashflows (in the mathematical sense: ) combined into an overall value per forecast period which are discounted.
[69][70][71][64]
And using the CAPM – or extensions – the discounting here is at the risk-free rate plus a premium linked to the uncertainty of the entity or project cash flows
[64]
(essentially, and combined).
Other developments here include[72]agency theory, which analyses the difficulties in motivating corporate management (the "agent"; in a different sense to the above) to act in the best interests of shareholders (the "principal"), rather than in their own interests; here emphasizing the issues interrelated with capital structure.
[73]Clean surplus accounting and the related residual income valuation provide a model that returns price as a function of earnings, expected returns, and change in book value, as opposed to dividends. This approach, to some extent, arises due to the implicit contradiction of seeing value as a function of dividends, while also holding that dividend policy cannot influence value per Modigliani and Miller's "Irrelevance principle"; see Dividend policy § Relevance of dividend policy.
As described, the typical application of real options is to capital budgeting type problems.
However, here, they are also applied to problems of capital structure and dividend policy, and to the related design of corporate securities;
[75]
and since stockholder and bondholders have different objective functions, in the analysis of the related agency problems.
[65]
In all of these cases, state-prices can provide the market-implied information relating to the corporate, as above, which is then applied to the analysis. For example, convertible bonds can (must) be priced consistent with the (recovered) state-prices of the corporate's equity.[21][69]
Market microstructure is concerned with the details of how exchange occurs in markets
(with Walrasian-, matching-, Fisher-, and
Arrow-Debreu markets as prototypes),
and "analyzes how specific trading mechanisms affect the price formation process",[77] examining the ways in which the processes of a market affect determinants of transaction costs, prices, quotes, volume, and trading behavior.
It has been used, for example, in providing explanations for long-standing exchange rate puzzles,[78] and for the equity premium puzzle.[79]
In contrast to the above classical approach, models here explicitly allow for (testing the impact of) market frictions and other imperfections;
see also market design.
These 'bottom-up' models "start from first principals of agent behavior",[84] with participants modifying their trading strategies having learned over time, and "are able to describe macro features [i.e. stylized facts] emerging from a soup of individual interacting strategies".[84]
Agent-based models depart further from the classical approach — the representative agent, as outlined — in that they introduce heterogeneity into the environment (thereby addressing, also, the aggregation problem).
As above, there is a very close link between:
the random walk hypothesis, with the associated belief that price changes should follow a normal distribution, on the one hand;
and market efficiency and rational expectations, on the other.
Wide departures from these are commonly observed, and there are thus, respectively, two main sets of challenges.
As discussed, the assumptions that market prices follow a random walk and that asset returns are normally distributed are fundamental. Empirical evidence, however, suggests that these assumptions may not hold, and that in practice, traders, analysts and risk managers frequently modify the "standard models" (see Kurtosis risk, Skewness risk, Long tail, Model risk).
In fact, Benoit Mandelbrot had discovered already in the 1960s
[85]
that changes in financial prices do not follow a normal distribution, the basis for much option pricing theory, although this observation was slow to find its way into mainstream financial economics.
[86]
Closely related is the volatility smile, where, as above, implied volatility – the volatility corresponding to the BSM price – is observed to differ as a function of strike price (i.e. moneyness), true only if the price-change distribution is non-normal, unlike that assumed by BSM. The term structure of volatility describes how (implied) volatility differs for related options with different maturities. An implied volatility surface is then a three-dimensional surface plot of volatility smile and term structure. These empirical phenomena negate the assumption of constant volatility – and log-normality – upon which Black–Scholes is built.[40][87]
Within institutions, the function of Black–Scholes is now, largely, to communicate prices via implied volatilities, much like bond prices are communicated via YTM; see Black–Scholes model § The volatility smile.
In consequence traders (and risk managers) now, instead, use "smile-consistent" models, firstly, when valuing derivatives not directly mapped to the surface, facilitating the pricing of other, i.e. non-quoted, strike/maturity combinations, or of non-European derivatives, and generally for hedging purposes.
The two main approaches are local volatility and stochastic volatility. The first returns the volatility which is "local" to each spot-time point of the finite difference- or simulation-based valuation; i.e. as opposed to implied volatility, which holds overall. In this way calculated prices – and numeric structures – are market-consistent in an arbitrage-free sense. The second approach assumes that the volatility of the underlying price is a stochastic process rather than a constant. Models here are first calibrated to observed prices, and are then applied to the valuation or hedging in question; the most common are Heston, SABR and CEV. This approach addresses certain problems identified with hedging under local volatility.[89]
Related to local volatility are the lattice-based implied-binomial and -trinomial trees – essentially a discretization of the approach – which are similarly, but less commonly,[20] used for pricing; these are built on state-prices recovered from the surface. Edgeworth binomial trees allow for a specified (i.e. non-Gaussian) skew and kurtosis in the spot price; priced here, options with differing strikes will return differing implied volatilities, and the tree can be calibrated to the smile as required.[90]
Similarly purposed (and derived) closed-form models were also developed.
[91]
As discussed, additional to assuming log-normality in returns, "classical" BSM-type models also (implicitly) assume the existence of a credit-risk-free environment, where one can perfectly replicate cashflows so as to fully hedge, and then discount at "the" risk-free-rate.
And therefore, post crisis, the various x-value adjustments must be employed, effectively correcting the risk-neutral value for counterparty- and funding-related risk.
These xVA are additional to any smile or surface effect. This is valid as the surface is built on price data relating to fully collateralized positions, and there is therefore no "double counting" of credit risk (etc.) when appending xVA. (Were this not the case, then each counterparty would have its own surface...)
As mentioned at top, mathematical finance (and particularly financial engineering) is more concerned with mathematical consistency (and market realities) than compatibility with economic theory, and the above "extreme event" approaches, smile-consistent modeling, and valuation adjustments should then be seen in this light. Recognizing this, critics of financial economics - especially vocal since the 2007–2008 financial crisis - suggest that instead, the theory needs revisiting almost entirely: [note 18]
"The current system, based on the idea that risk is distributed in the shape of a bell curve, is flawed... The problem is [that economists and practitioners] never abandon the bell curve. They are like medieval astronomers who believe the sun revolves around the earth and are furiously tweaking their geo-centric math in the face of contrary evidence. They will never get this right; they need their Copernicus."[92]
As seen, a common assumption is that financial decision makers act rationally; see Homo economicus. Recently, however, researchers in experimental economics and experimental finance have challenged this assumption empirically. These assumptions are also challenged theoretically, by behavioral finance, a discipline primarily concerned with the limits to rationality of economic agents.
[note 19]
For related criticisms re corporate finance theory vs its practice see:.[93] Various persistent market anomalies have also been documented as consistent with and complementary to price or return distortions – e.g. size premiums – which appear to contradict the efficient-market hypothesis. Within these market anomalies, calendar effects are the most commonly referenced group.
Related to these are various of the economic puzzles, concerning phenomena similarly contradicting the theory. The equity premium puzzle, as one example, arises in that the difference between the observed returns on stocks as compared to government bonds is consistently higher than the risk premium rational equity investors should demand, an "abnormal return". For further context see Random walk hypothesis § A non-random walk hypothesis, and sidebar for specific instances.
More generally, and, again, particularly following the 2007–2008 financial crisis, financial economics and mathematical finance have been subjected to deeper criticism; notable here is Nassim Nicholas Taleb, who claims that the prices of financial assets cannot be characterized by the simple models currently in use, rendering much of current practice at best irrelevant, and, at worst, dangerously misleading; see Black swan theory, Taleb distribution.
A topic of general interest has thus been financial crises,
[94]
and the failure of (financial) economics to model (and predict) these.
However, studies show that despite inefficiencies, asset prices generally follow a random walk, making it difficult to consistently outperform market averages and achieve "alpha".[95] As an explanation for these inefficiencies, institutional limits to arbitrage are sometimes referenced (as opposed to factors directly contradictory to the theory). The practical implication is that passive investing (e.g. via low-cost index funds) should, on average, serve better than any other active strategy.[96][note 20]
^The theorem of Franco Modigliani and Merton Miller is often called the "capital structure irrelevance principle"; it is presented in two key papers
of 1958,[24]
and 1963.[25]
^John Burr Williams published his "Theory" in 1938; NPV was recommended to corporate managers by Joel Dean in 1951.
^In fact, "Fisher (1930, [The Theory of Interest]) is the seminal work for most of the financial theory of investments during the twentieth century… Fisher develops the first formal equilibrium model of an economy with both intertemporal exchange and production. In so doing, at one swoop, he not only derives present value calculations as a natural economic outcome in calculating wealth, he also justifies the maximization of present value as the goal of production and derives determinants of the interest rates that are used to calculate present value."[12]: 55
^"BSM" – two seminal 1973 papers by Fischer Black and Myron Scholes,[38]
and Robert C. Merton[39] – is consistent with "previous versions of the formula" of Louis Bachelier (1900) and Edward O. Thorp (1967);[40] although these were more "actuarial" in flavor, and had not established risk-neutral discounting.[13]Vinzenz Bronzin (1908) produced very early results, also. Case Sprenkle (1961) [41] had published a formula for the price of a call-option which, with adjustments, satisfied the BSM partial differential equation.[42]
^Kiyosi Itô published his Lemma in 1944. Paul Samuelson[43] introduced this area of mathematics into finance in 1965;
Robert Merton promoted continuous stochastic calculus and continuous-time processes from 1969.
[44]
^The single-index model was developed by William Sharpe in 1963.
[47]
APT was developed by Stephen Ross in 1976.
[48]
^The universal portfolio algorithm was published by Thomas M. Cover in 1991. The Black–Litterman model was developed in 1990 at Goldman Sachs by Fischer Black and Robert Litterman, and published in 1991.
^
Simulation was first applied to (corporate) finance by David B. Hertz in 1964.
Decision trees, a standard operations research tool, were applied to corporate finance also in the 1960s.[67]
Real options in corporate finance were first discussed by Stewart Myers in 1977.
^The Benchmark here is the pioneering AFM of the Santa Fe Institute developed in the early 1990s. See [84] for discussion of other early models.
^ abcdefghijRubinstein, Mark. (2005). "Great Moments in Financial Economics: IV. The Fundamental Theorem (Part I)", Journal of Investment Management, Vol. 3, No. 4, Fourth Quarter 2005; ~ (2006). Part II, Vol. 4, No. 1, First Quarter 2006. (See under "External links".)
^Arrow, K. J.; Debreu, G. (1954). "Existence of an equilibrium for a competitive economy". Econometrica. 22 (3): 265–290. doi:10.2307/1907353. JSTOR1907353.
^McKenzie, Lionel W. (1954). "On Equilibrium in Graham's Model of World Trade and Other Competitive Systems". Econometrica. 22 (2): 147–161. doi:10.2307/1907539. JSTOR1907539.
^ abSee Luenberger's Investment Science, under Bibliography.
^Modigliani, F.; Miller, M. (1958). "The Cost of Capital, Corporation Finance and the Theory of Investment". American Economic Review. 48 (3): 261–297. JSTOR1809766.
^Modigliani, F.; Miller, M. (1963). "Corporate income taxes and the cost of capital: a correction". American Economic Review. 53 (3): 433–443. JSTOR1809167.
^de Finetti, B. (1940): Il problema dei “Pieni”. Giornale dell’ Istituto Italiano degli Attuari 11, 1–88; translation (Barone, L. (2006)): The problem of full-risk insurances. Chapter I. The risk within a single accounting period. Journal of Investment Management 4(3), 19–43
^Jensen, Michael C. and Smith, Clifford W., "The Theory of Corporate Finance: A Historical Overview". In: The Modern Theory of Corporate Finance, New York: McGraw-Hill Inc., pp. 2–20, 1984.
^Black, Fischer; Myron Scholes (1973). "The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities". Journal of Political Economy. 81 (3): 637–654. doi:10.1086/260062. S2CID154552078. [1]
^Merton, Robert C. "Lifetime Portfolio Selection under Uncertainty: The Continuous-Time Case." The Review of Economics and Statistics 51 (August 1969): 247-257.
^Carriere, Jacques (1996). "Valuation of the early-exercise price for options using simulations and nonparametric regression". Insurance: Mathematics and Economics. 19: 19–30. doi:10.1016/S0167-6687(96)00004-2.
^Kritzman, Mark (2017). "An Interview with Nobel Laureate Harry M. Markowitz". Financial Analysts Journal. 73 (4): 16–21. doi:10.2469/faj.v73.n4.3. S2CID158093964.
^ abSee Kruschwitz and Löffler under Bibliography.
^See for example Pg 217 of: Jackson, Mary; Mike Staunton (2001). Advanced modelling in finance using Excel and VBA. New Jersey: Wiley. ISBN0-471-49922-6.
Louis Eeckhoudt; Christian Gollier, Harris Schlesinger (2005). Economic and Financial Decisions Under Risk. Princeton University Press. ISBN978-0-691-12215-1.
Yvan Lengwiler (2006). Microfoundations of Financial Economics: An Introduction to General Equilibrium Asset Pricing. Princeton University Press. ISBN978-0691126319.
Stephen F. LeRoy; Jan Werner (2000). Principles of Financial Economics. Cambridge University Press. ISBN978-0521586054.
Leonard C. MacLean; William T. Ziemba (2013). Handbook of the Fundamentals of Financial Decision Making. World Scientific. ISBN978-9814417341.
Joseph Ogden; Frank C. Jen; Philip F. O'Connor (2002). Advanced Corporate Finance. Prentice Hall. ISBN978-0130915689.
Pascal Quiry; Yann Le Fur; Antonio Salvi; Maurizio Dallochio; Pierre Vernimmen (2011). Corporate Finance: Theory and Practice (3rd ed.). Wiley. ISBN978-1119975588.
يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم في تطوير هذه المقالة من خلال إضافة مصادر موثوق بها. أي معلومات غير موثقة يمكن التشكيك بها وإزالتها. (فبراير 2019) نادي ديربن سيتي تأسس عام مايو 1959 البلد جنوب إفريقيا تعديل مصدري - تعديل نادي ديربن سيتي كان نادي
For television shows that do not follow a narrative and are not classified as teleserye, see List of Philippine television shows. The following is list of Philippine drama series (also known as teleserye, Filipino telenovelas or P-drama) aired in the Philippine television. 2023 Television series Original network Status Total no. of episodes Notes FPJ's Batang Quiapo Kapamilya Channel On-going – Team A TV5 On-going – Kurdapya (Curdapia) TV5 On-going – For the Love TV5 On-going – Pira-P...
Saeberto de Essex Rey de Essex Reinado 604 - 616Predecesor SleddSucesor Sexred SaewardInformación personalFallecimiento 616FamiliaPadre SleddMadre RiculaHijos Sexred Saeward[editar datos en Wikidata] Sæberht, Saberht o Sæbert (d. c. 616) fue un rey de Essex (r. c. 604 – c. 616), en sucesión de su padre, el rey Sledd.[1] Es conocido como el primer rey de los sajones del este en convertirse al cristianismo. La fuente principal para su reinado la Historia ecclesiastica gen...
لمعانٍ أخرى، طالع الحكم (توضيح). الحكمThe Verdictمعلومات عامةالصنف الفني دراماالموضوع كحولية تاريخ الصدور 1982مدة العرض 129 دقيقةاللغة الأصلية الإنجليزيةالبلد الولايات المتحدةموقع التصوير تورونتو الجوائز المجلس الوطني للمراجعة: الأفلام العشر الأولى الطاقمالمخرج ...
Argentine footballer (1922–2020) Jorge Benegas Personal informationDate of birth (1922-11-30)30 November 1922Date of death 26 August 2020(2020-08-26) (aged 97)Position(s) DefenderInternational careerYears Team Apps (Gls)1956–1957 Argentina 5 (0) Jorge Benegas (30 November 1922 – 26 August 2020) was an Argentine footballer. He played in five matches for the Argentina national football team in 1956 and 1957.[1] He was also part of Argentina's squad for the 1957 South American...
Angola Angolanische Botschaft in Berlin Logo Staatliche Ebene bilateral Stellung der Behörde Botschaft Aufsichtsbehörde(n) Außenministerium Bestehen seit 1975 Hauptsitz Deutschland Berlin Botschafterin Balbina Malheiros Dias da Silva Mitarbeiter 8[1] Website www.botschaftangola.de Botschaftsgebäude Werderscher Markt Ehemaliger Botschaftssitz in der Wallstraße 59 Die angolanische Botschaft in Berlin ist die diplomatische Vertretung der Republik Angola in der Bundesrepub...
У Вікіпедії є статті про інші значення цього терміна: Віковий дуб. Віковий дуб 48°27′33″ пн. ш. 28°11′08″ сх. д. / 48.45944000002777585° пн. ш. 28.185830000027777942° сх. д. / 48.45944000002777585; 28.185830000027777942Координати: 48°27′33″ пн. ш. 28°11′08″ сх. д. / 48.4594400000277...
Historic house in Michigan, United States United States historic placeRadka–Bradley HouseU.S. National Register of Historic Places Radka–Bradley House in 1921Show map of MichiganShow map of the United StatesLocation176 W. Michigan Ave., Rogers City, MichiganCoordinates45°25′13″N 83°49′5″W / 45.42028°N 83.81806°W / 45.42028; -83.81806Area0.5 acres (0.20 ha)Built byGeorge J. RadkaArchitectural styleBungalow/American CraftsmanNRHP reference&...
У этого термина существуют и другие значения, см. Михайло-Архангельский собор. православный храмМихайло-Архангельский собор 56°19′41″ с. ш. 44°00′06″ в. д.HGЯO Страна Россия Город Нижний Новгород Конфессия Православие Епархия Нижегородская Благочиние Нижегород...
School in the United StatesNavarro Early College High SchoolAddress1201 Payton Gin RoadAustin, Texas78758United StatesCoordinates30°21′37″N 97°42′28″W / 30.36028°N 97.70778°W / 30.36028; -97.70778InformationMottoWhat Starts Here Changes EducationEstablished1961School districtAustin Independent School DistrictPrincipalSteven CovinTeaching staff114.78 (FTE)[1]Grades9-12Enrollment1,586 (2017-18)[1]Student to teacher ratio13.82[1]Color(s...
This article may have been created or edited in return for undisclosed payments, a violation of Wikipedia's terms of use. It may require cleanup to comply with Wikipedia's content policies, particularly neutral point of view. (September 2017) Diana EdenBorn1940NationalityAmericanAlma materUniversity of TorontoOccupationCostume designerAwardsNominee for a Primetime Emmy Award and two Daytime Emmy Awards; winner of a Los Angeles Drama Critics Circle Award Diana Eden (born Diana Moore Ede, ...
Not to be confused with B-class Melbourne tram (1917). B-classB2 2060 in PTV livery on route 75 in February 2023Refurbished B2 class interiorManufacturerComeng/ABBAssemblyDandenongConstructed1984-1994Number built132Number in service130 (January 2023)Fleet numbers B1 2001–B1 2002 B2 2003–B2 2132 Capacity B1/B2: 76/110 B2 (Apollo): 40/120 (seated/standing)Depot(s) Brunswick Camberwell Essendon Glenhuntly SpecificationsTrain length B1: 23.5 m (77 ft 1 in) B2: 23.63 m...
Constituency of the Madhya Pradesh legislative assembly in India SemariyaConstituency No. 69 for the Madhya Pradesh Legislative AssemblyConstituency detailsCountryIndiaRegionCentral IndiaStateMadhya PradeshDistrictRewaLS constituencyRewaTotal electors197,764ReservationNoneMember of Legislative Assembly16th Madhya Pradesh Legislative AssemblyIncumbent K. P. Tripathi PartyBharatiya Janta PartyElected year2018 Semariya Assembly constituency is one of the 230 Vidhan Sabha (Legislative Assembly) c...
В статье есть список источников, но не хватает сносок. Без сносок сложно определить, из какого источника взято каждое отдельное утверждение. Вы можете улучшить статью, проставив сноски на источники, подтверждающие информацию. Сведения без сносок могут быть удалены. (8 дек...
Gareth Llewellyn Nazionalità Galles Altezza 198 cm Peso 114 kg Rugby Ruolo Seconda linea Squadra Bristol Carriera Squadre di club ?-?Llanharan RFC?-? Neath?-? Harlequins?-2004 Ospreys2004-2005 Narbona2005-2008 Bristol Nazionale 1989-2004 Galles92 (24) Modifica dati su Wikidata · Manuale Gareth Llewellyn (Cardiff, 27 febbraio 1969) è un rugbista a 15 gallese che gioca da seconda linea. Llewellyn ha cominciato la sua carriera nel Llanharan RFC...
Belgian opera singer Cécile ThévenetCécile Thévenet, as Charlotte in Werther, from a 1905 publication.Born22 November 1872BrugesDied15 March 1956MeudonNationalityBelgianOther namesCécilie ThévenetOccupationopera singer Cécile Thévenet (1872-1956) was a Belgian opera singer. Early life Cécile Thévenet, in costume for Carmen, from a 1905 publication. Cécile Thévenet was born in Bruges, the daughter of Alphonse Thévenet and Anne Van Vyve. Her father was a music teacher and bari...
Bae Soo-binBae Soo-bin pada Desember 2018LahirYoon Tae WookPekerjaanAktorTahun aktif2004—sekarang Nama KoreaHangul윤태욱 Hanja尹泰旭 Alih AksaraYun Tae-ukMcCune–ReischauerYun T'aeukNama panggungHangul배수빈 Hanja裴秀彬 Alih AksaraBae Su-binMcCune–ReischauerPae Subin Bae Soo-bin (lahir Yoon Tae-wook lahir 9 Desember 1976) adalah pemeran Korea Selatan.[1][2][3] Ia paling dikenal untuk perannya dalam drama televisi Brilliant Legacy, Temptation of a...
Guillermo Vilas erzielte mit 46 Matches in Folge die bislang längste Siegesserie im Herrentennis Die Liste der längsten Siegesserien im Herrentennis enthält alle Tennisspieler, denen es während der Open Era gelungen ist, im Einzel 25 oder mehr Matches in Folge für sich zu entscheiden. Berücksichtigt werden dabei gemäß der offiziellen Zählweise der ATP Siege im Hauptfeld der ATP World Tour und ihrer Vorgängerserien, bei den Grand-Slam-Turnieren, Olympischen Spielen sowie im Davis Cup...
Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!