Economic history is the study of history using methodological tools from economics or with a special attention to economic phenomena. Research is conducted using a combination of historical methods, statistical methods and the application of economic theory to historical situations and institutions. The field can encompass a wide variety of topics, including equality, finance, technology, labour, and business. It emphasizes historicizing the economy itself, analyzing it as a dynamic entity and attempting to provide insights into the way it is structured and conceived.
Arnold Toynbee made the case for combining economics and history in his study of the Industrial Revolution, saying, "I believe economics today is much too dissociated from history. Smith and Malthus had historical minds. However, Ricardo – who set the pattern of modern textbooks – had a mind that was entirely unhistorical." There were several advantages in combining economics and history according to Toynbee. To begin with, it improved economic understanding. "We see abstract propositions in a new light when studying them in relation to historical facts. Propositions become more vivid and truthful." Meanwhile, studying history with economics makes history easier to understand. Economics teaches us to look out for the right facts in reading history and makes matters such as introducing enclosures, machinery, or new currencies more intelligible. Economics also teaches careful deductive reasoning. "The habits of mind it instils are even more valuable than the knowledge of principles it gives. Without these habits, the mass of their materials can overwhelm students of historical facts."[3]
In late-nineteenth-century Germany, scholars at a number of universities, led by Gustav von Schmoller, developed the historical school of economic history. It argued that there were no universal truths in history, emphasizing the importance of historical context without quantitative analysis. This historical approach dominated German and French scholarship for most of the 20th century. The historical school of economics included other economists such as Max Weber and Joseph Schumpeter who reasoned that careful analysis of human actions, cultural norms, historical context, and mathematical support was key to historical analysis. The approach was spread to Great Britain by William Ashley (University of Oxford) and dominated British economic history for much of the 20th century. Britain's first professor in the subject was George Unwin at the University of Manchester.[4][5] Meanwhile, in France, economic history was heavily influenced by the Annales School from the early 20th century to the present. It exerts a worldwide influence through its journal Annales. Histoire, Sciences Sociales.[6]
Treating economic history as a discrete academic discipline has been a contentious issue for many years. Academics at the London School of Economics and the University of Cambridge had numerous disputes over the separation of economics and economic history in the interwar era. Cambridge economists believed that pure economics involved a component of economic history and that the two were inseparably entangled. Those at the LSE believed that economic history warranted its own courses, research agenda and academic chair separated from mainstream economics. In the initial period of the subject's development, the LSE position of separating economic history from economics won out. Many universities in the UK developed independent programmes in economic history rooted in the LSE model. Indeed, the Economic History Society had its inauguration at LSE in 1926 and the University of Cambridge eventually established its own economic history programme.
In the United States, the field of economic history was largely subsumed into other fields of economics following the cliometric revolution of the 1960s.[7][8] To many it became seen as a form of applied economics rather than a stand-alone discipline. Cliometrics, also known as the New Economic History, refers to the systematic use of economic theory and econometric techniques to the study of economic history. The term was originally coined by Jonathan R. T. Hughes and Stanley Reiter and refers to Clio, who was the muse of history and heroic poetry in Greek mythology. One of the most famous cliometric economic historians is Douglass North, who argued that it is the task of economic history to elucidate the historical dimensions of economies through time.[9] Cliometricians argue their approach is necessary because the application of theory is crucial in writing solid economic history, while historians generally oppose this view warning against the risk of generating anachronisms.
Early cliometrics was a type of counterfactual history. However, counterfactualism was not its distinctive feature; it combined neoclassical economics with quantitative methods in order to explain human choices based on constraints.[10] Some have argued that cliometrics had its heyday in the 1960s and 1970s and that it is now neglected by economists and historians.[11] In response to North and Robert Fogel's Nobel Memorial Prize in Economics in 1993, Harvard University economist (and future Nobel winner) Claudia Goldin argued that:
economic history is not a handmaiden of economics but a distinct field of scholarship. Economic history was a scholarly discipline long before it became cliometrics. Its practitioners were economists and historians studying the histories of economies... The new economic history, or cliometrics, formalized economic history in a manner similar to the injection of mathematical models and statistics into the rest of economics.[12]
The relationship between economic history, economics and history has long been the subject of intense discussion, and the debates of recent years echo those of early contributors. There has long been a school of thought among economic historians that splits economic history—the study of how economic phenomena evolved in the past—from historical economics—testing the generality of economic theory using historical episodes. US economic historian Charles P. Kindleberger explained this position in his 1990 book Historical Economics: Art or Science?.[13] Economic historian Robert Skidelsky (University of Cambridge) argued that economic theory often employs ahistorical models and methodologies that do not take into account historical context.[14]Yale University economist Irving Fisher already wrote in 1933 on the relationship between economics and economic history in his "Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions":
The study of dis-equilibrium may proceed in either of two ways. We may take as our unit for study an actual historical case of great dis-equilibrium, such as, say, the panic of 1873; or we may take as our unit for study any constituent tendency, such as, say, deflation, and discover its general laws, relations to, and combinations with, other tendencies. The former study revolves around events, or facts; the latter, around tendencies. The former is primarily economic history; the latter is primarily economic science. Both sorts of studies are proper and important. Each helps the other. The panic of 1873 can only be understood in light of the various tendencies involved—deflation and other; and deflation can only be understood in the light of various historical manifestations—1873 and other.[15]
Scope and focus of economic history today
The past three decades have witnessed the widespread closure of separate economic history departments and programmes in the UK and the integration of the discipline into either history or economics departments.[16] Only the LSE retains a separate economic history department and stand-alone undergraduate and graduate programme in economic history. Cambridge, Glasgow, LSE, Oxford, Queen's, and Warwick together train the vast majority of economic historians coming through the British higher education system today, but do so as part of economics or history degrees. Meanwhile, there have never been specialist economic history graduate programs at universities anywhere in the US. However, economic history remains a special field component of leading economics PhD programs, including University of California, Berkeley, Harvard University, Northwestern University, Princeton University, the University of Chicago and Yale University.
Despite the pessimistic view on the state of the discipline espoused by many of its practitioners, economic history remains an active field of social scientific inquiry. Indeed, it has seen something of a resurgence in interest since 2000, perhaps driven by research conducted at universities in continental Europe rather than the UK and the US.[17] The overall number of economic historians in the world is estimated at 10,400, with Japan and China as well as the U.K and the U.S. ranking highest in numbers. Some less developed countries, however, are not sufficiently integrated in the world economic history community, among others, Senegal, Brazil and Vietnam.[18]
Since the 2007–2008 financial crisis, scholars have become more interested in a field which may be called new new economic history. Scholars have tended to move away from narrowly quantitative studies toward institutional, social, and cultural history affecting the evolution of economies.[21][a 1] The focus of these studies is frequently on "persistence", as past events are linked to present outcomes.[22][23]Columbia UniversityeconomistCharles Calomiris argued that this new field showed 'how historical (path-dependent) processes governed changes in institutions and markets.'[24] However, this trend has been criticized, most forcefully by Francesco Boldizzoni, as a form of economic imperialism "extending the neoclassical explanatory model to the realm of social relations."[25]
Conversely, economists in other specializations have started to write a new kind of economic history which makes use of historical data to understand the present day.[a 2] A major development in this genre was the publication of Thomas Piketty's Capital in the Twenty-First Century (2013). The book described the rise in wealth and income inequality since the 18th century, arguing that large concentrations of wealth lead to social and economic instability. Piketty also advocated a system of global progressive wealth taxes to correct rising inequality. The book was selected as a New York Times best seller and received numerous awards. The book was well received by some of the world's major economists, including Paul Krugman, Robert Solow, and Ben Bernanke.[26] Books in response to Piketty's book include After Piketty: The Agenda for Economics and Inequality, by Heather Boushey, J. Bradford DeLong, and Marshall Steinbaum (eds.) (2017), Pocket Piketty by Jesper Roine (2017), and Anti-Piketty: Capital for the 21st Century, by Jean-Philippe Delsol, Nicolas Lecaussin, Emmanuel Martin (2017). One economist argued that Piketty's book was "Nobel-Prize worthy" and noted that it had changed the global discussion on how economic historians study inequality.[27] It has also sparked new conversations in the disciplines of public policy.[28]
In addition to the mainstream in economic history, there is a parallel development in the field influenced by Karl Marx and Marxian economics.[29][30] Marx used historical analysis to interpret the role of class and class as a central issue in history. He debated with the "classical" economists (a term he coined), including Adam Smith and David Ricardo. In turn, Marx's legacy in economic history has been to critique the findings of neoclassical economists.[31] Marxist analysis also confronts economic determinism, the theory that economic relationships are the foundation of political and societal institutions. Marx abstracted the idea of a "capitalist mode of production" as a way of identifying the transition from feudalism to capitalism.[32] This has influenced some scholars, such as Maurice Dobb, to argue that feudalism declined because of peasants' struggles for freedom and the growing inefficiency of feudalism as a system of production.[33] In turn, in what was later coined the Brenner debate, Paul Sweezy, a Marxian economist, challenged Dobb's definition of feudalism and its focus only on western Europe.[34]
A new field, called "history of capitalism" by researchers engaged in it, has emerged in US history departments since about the year 2000. It includes many topics traditionally associated with the field of economic history, such as insurance, banking and regulation, the political dimension of business, and the impact of capitalism on the middle classes, the poor and women and minorities. The field has particularly focused on the contribution of slavery to the rise of the US economy in the nineteenth century. The field utilizes the existing research of business history, but has sought to make it more relevant to the concerns of history departments in the United States, including by having limited or no discussion of individual business enterprises.[35][36] Historians of capitalism have countered these critiques, citing the issues with economic history. As University of Chicago professor of history Jonathan Levy states, "modern economic history began with industrialization and urbanization, and, even then, environmental considerations were subsidiary, if not nonexistent."[37]
Scholars have critiqued the history of capitalism because it does not focus on systems of production, circulation, and distribution.[38] Some have criticized its lack of social scientific methods and its ideological biases.[39] As a result, a new academic journal, Capitalism: A Journal of History and Economics, was founded at the University of Pennsylvania under the direction of Marc Flandreau (University of Pennsylvania), Julia Ott (The New School, New York) and Francesca Trivellato (Institute for Advanced Study, Princeton) to widen the scope of the field. The journal's goal is to bring together "historians and social scientists interested in the material and intellectual aspects of modern economic life."[40]
Academic journals and societies
The first journal specializing in the field of economic history was The Economic History Review, founded in 1927, as the main publication of the Economic History Society. The first journal featured a publication by Professor Sir William Ashley, the first Professor of Economic History in the English-speaking world, who described the emerging field of economic history. The discipline existed alongside long-standing fields such as political history, religious history, and military history as one that focused on humans' interactions with 'visible happenings'. He continued, '[economic history] primarily and unless expressly extended, the history of actual human practice with respect to the material basis of life. The visible happenings with regard-to use the old formula-to "the production, distribution, and consumption of wealth" form our wide enough field'.[41]
Later, the Economic History Association established another academic journal, The Journal of Economic History, in 1941 as a way of expanding the discipline in the United States.[42] The first president of the Economic History Association, Edwin F. Gay, described the aim of economic history was to provide new perspectives in the economics and history disciplines: 'An adequate equipment with two skills, that of the historian and the economist, is not easily acquired, but experience shows that it is both necessary and possible'.[43] Other related academic journals have broadened the lens with which economic history is studied. These interdisciplinary journals include the Business History Review, European Review of Economic History, Enterprise and Society, and Financial History Review.
Have a very healthy respect for the study of economic history, because that's the raw material out of which any of your conjectures or testings will come.
Several economists have won Nobel prizes for contributions to economic history or contributions to economics that are commonly applied in economic history.
Simon Kuznets won the Nobel Memorial Prize in Economic Sciences ("the Nobel Memorial Prize") in 1971 "for his empirically founded interpretation of economic growth which has led to new and deepened insight into the economic and social structure and process of development".
Arthur Lewis won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1979 for his contributions in the field of economic development through historical context.
Milton Friedman won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1976 for "his achievements in the fields of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilization policy".
Robert Fogel and Douglass North won the Nobel Memorial Prize in 1993 for "having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods in order to explain economic and institutional change".
Claudia Goldin, who won the Nobel in 2023 for 'having advanced our understanding of women's labor market outcomes', began her career researching the history of the US southern economy and was President of the Economic History Association in 1999/2000.
^Rockman, Seth (2014). "What Makes the History of Capitalism Newsworthy?". Journal of the Early Republic. 34 (3): 439–466. doi:10.1353/jer.2014.0043. S2CID143866857.
^Arnold Toynbee's The Industrial Revolution: A Translation into Modern English, Kindle edition, 2020, pages1-2. ISBN9780906321744. First published 1884.
^Berg, M. (1992). The first women economic historians. The Economic History Review, 45(2), 308–329.
^Robert Forster, "Achievements of the Annales school." Journal of Economic History 38.01 (1978): 58–76. in JSTORArchived 2018-10-31 at the Wayback Machine
^North, Douglass C. (1978). "Structure and Performance: The Task of Economic History". Journal of Economic Literature. 16 (3): 963–978. JSTOR2723471.
^North, Douglass C. (1978). "Structure and Performance: The Task of Economic History". Journal of Economic Literature. 16 (3).
^Whaples, Robert (2010). "Is Economic History a Neglected Field of Study?". Historically Speaking. 11 (2): 17–20 & 20–27 (responses). doi:10.1353/hsp.0.0109. S2CID162209922.
^Fisher, Irving (1933). "Debt-Deflation Theory of Great Depressions". Econometrica. 1 (4): 337–38. doi:10.2307/1907327. JSTOR1907327.
^Blum, Matthias; Colvin, Christopher L. (2018), Blum, Matthias; Colvin, Christopher L. (eds.), "Introduction, or Why We Started This Project", An Economist's Guide to Economic History, Palgrave Studies in Economic History, Springer International Publishing, pp. 1–10, doi:10.1007/978-3-319-96568-0_1, ISBN978-3-319-96568-0
^Baten, Jörg; Muschallik, Julia (2012). "On the Status and Future of Economic History". Economic History of Developing Regions. 27: 93–113. doi:10.1080/20780389.2012.682390. S2CID155697900.
^Irwin, Neil (30 March 2015). "The New York Times". Now That Ben Bernanke Is Blogging, Here's What He Should Write About. Archived from the original on 17 December 2019. Retrieved 17 December 2019.
^Krugman, Paul (8 May 2014). "Why We're in a New Gilded Age". The New York Review of Books. Archived from the original on 4 April 2015. Retrieved 22 February 2020.
^Heller, Henry (2018). A Marxist History of Capitalism. Routledge.
^Meek, Ronald L. (1956). Studies in the Labour Theory of Value. New York.{{cite book}}: CS1 maint: location missing publisher (link)
^Cohen, Jon S. (1978). "The Achievements of Economic History: The Marxist School". The Journal of Economic History. 38 (1): 29–57. doi:10.1017/S002205070008815X. S2CID153934134.
^Dobb, Maurice (1946). Studies in the Development of Capitalism. Routledge.
^Sweezy, Paul (1950). "The Transition From Feudalism To Capitalism". Science & Society. 14 (2).
^Ashley, William (1927). "The Place of Economic History in University Studies". The Economic History Review. 1 (1): 1–11. doi:10.2307/2590667. JSTOR2590667.
^Heaton, Herbert (1941). "The Early History of the Economic History Association". The Journal of Economic History. 1.
Cameron, Rondo; Neal, Larry (2003). A Concise Economic History of the World: From Paleolithic Times to the Present (4th ed.). New York: Oxford University Press. ISBN0195127056.
Cipolla, C. M. (1991). Between History and Economics: An Introduction to Economic History. Oxford: Blackwell. ISBN0631166815.
Mokyr, Joyr (2003). "Economic Encyclopaedia". The Oxford Encyclopedia of Economic History. 5 vols. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Archived from the original on 2011-06-29. Retrieved 2010-04-05.
Not to be confused with the 2014 Punjabi film Dil Vil Pyaar Vyaar. 2002 Indian filmDil Vil Pyar VyarDirected byAnant MahadevanWritten byTigmanshu DhuliaAnant MahadevanVivek VaswaniSanjeev Puri (Dialogues)Screenplay bySujit SenStory byVivek VaswaniProduced byVivek VaswaniMetalight ProductionsStarringR. MadhavanJimmy ShergillSanjay SuriNamrata ShirodkarSonali KulkarniHrishita BhattCinematographyRajkumarEdited bySanjib DattaMusic byBabloo ChakravorthyProductioncompaniesMetalight ProductionsInsig...
«Піна»(рос. «Пена») Жанр комедіяРежисер Олександр СтефановичСценарист Сергій МихалковОлександр СтефановичУ головних ролях Анатолій Папанов Лідія Смирнова Леонід КуравльовОператор Елізбар КараваєвКомпозитор Борис РичковХудожник Валентин ВирвичКінокомпанія Мосфіл...
سفارة الدنمارك في النرويج الدنمارك النرويج الإحداثيات 59°55′05″N 10°41′37″E / 59.918°N 10.6936°E / 59.918; 10.6936 البلد النرويج المكان بلدية أوسلو [لغات أخرى] الموقع الالكتروني الموقع الرسمي تعديل مصدري - تعديل سفارة الدنمارك في النرويج هي أرفع تمثيل دبلوما...
Дональдсон — термін, який має кілька значень. Ця сторінка значень містить посилання на статті про кожне з них.Якщо ви потрапили сюди за внутрішнім посиланням, будь ласка, поверніться та виправте його так, щоб воно вказувало безпосередньо на потрібну статтю.@ пошук посила...
هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (مارس 2021) جانيت بيسيرا معلومات شخصية الميلاد سنة 1965 (العمر 57–58 سنة) كاغواس مواطنة بورتوريكو الحياة العملية المدرسة الأم جامعة بورتوريكو [لغات أخرى]R...
Bài viết này là một bài mồ côi vì không có bài viết khác liên kết đến nó. Vui lòng tạo liên kết đến bài này từ các bài viết liên quan; có thể thử dùng công cụ tìm liên kết. (tháng 7 năm 2018) Bài viết này cần thêm chú thích nguồn gốc để kiểm chứng thông tin. Mời bạn giúp hoàn thiện bài viết này bằng cách bổ sung chú thích tới các nguồn đáng tin cậy. Các nội dung không có nguồn có...
Fannie FarmerLahirFannie Merritt Farmer(1857-03-23)23 Maret 1857Boston, Massachusetts, A.SMeninggal15 Januari 1915(1915-01-15) (umur 57)PekerjaanKoki, penulis buku resepDikenal atasMenulis buku Boston Cooking-School Cook Book Fannie Farmer merupakan seorang juru masak wanita yang memiliki nama lengkap Fannie Merritt Farmer. Fannie Merritt Farmer lahir pada tanggal 23 Maret 1857 di Boston, Massachusetts, Amerika Serikat. DIa adalah sosok wanita tanggung yang dengan segala keterbatasan fis...
Rich WilliamsonChair of the Illinois Republican PartyIn office1999–2001Preceded byHarold SmithSucceeded byLee A. DanielsAssistant Secretary of State for International Organization AffairsIn officeFebruary 18, 1988 – March 19, 1989PresidentRonald ReaganGeorge H. W. BushPreceded byAlan KeyesSucceeded byJohn BoltonUnited States Ambassador to the United Nations International Organizations in ViennaIn officeMay 17, 1983 – January 15, 1985PresidentRonald ReaganPreceded byPos...
First World War event Bombardment of Great Yarmouth and LowestoftPart of the First World WarNorth SeaDate24 April 1916Locationthe North Sea, including off the coast of Great Yarmouth and Lowestoft, England.Result InconclusiveBelligerents British Empire German EmpireCommanders and leaders Com. Reginald Tyrwhitt Vice Admiral David Beatty Admiral John Jellicoe Rear-Admiral Friedrich Boedicker Vice-Admiral Reinhard ScheerCasualties and losses 25 killed19 wounded2 light cruisers damage...
Scriptures of esoteric Hinduism For Buddhist Tantric texts, see Tantras (Buddhism). For Tantric Buddhism, see Vajrayana. For the practice of Tantra, see Tantra. This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources in this article. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Tantras Hinduism – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (August 2007...
Опис Пейзажі села. Зима 1995 Джерело власне фото Час створення 1995 Автор зображення В.Кириченко Ліцензія Цей файл було добровільно передано в суспільне надбання його автором — користувачем української Вікіпедії. [[Користувач:{{{1}}}|{{{1}}}]] віддає усі права на використання ц...
1958 Polish film by Andrzej Munk EroicaDirected byAndrzej MunkWritten byJerzy Stefan StawińskiStarringEdward DziewońskiTadeusz ŁomnickiLeon NiemczykCinematographyJerzy WójcikMusic byJan KrenzDistributed byKADRRelease date1958Running time87 minutesCountryPolandLanguagePolish Eroica (released in some territories as Heroism) is a 1958 Polish film by Andrzej Munk, and his second feature film after Man on the Tracks (1956). Eroica is composed of two separate stories, presenting satirical criti...
SLB Negeri A Pajajaran Kota BandungInformasiDidirikan24 Juli 1901; 122 tahun lalu (1901-07-24)JenisNegeriAkreditasiA[1].Nomor Pokok Sekolah Nasional20280593Kepala SekolahGun Gun Guntara, S.PdKurikulumKurikulum 2013 Kurikulum MerdekaStatusSekolah Standar NasionalAlamatLokasiJl. Pajajaran No. 50 Kelurahan Pasirkaliki, Kecamatan Cicendo, Bandung 40171, Jawa Barat, IndonesiaTel./Faks.+62-22-4203327Moto SLB Negeri A Pajajaran Bandung merupakan sekolah luar biasa Negeri yang...
Benedictine monk (950–1022) Notker Labeo, relief at the Abbey of St Gall. Notker Labeo (c. 950 – 28 June 1022), also known as Notker the German (Latin: Notcerus Teutonicus) or Notker III, was a Benedictine monk active as a scholar and teacher. He was the first commentator on Aristotle active in the Middle Ages and translated the works of earlier Latin writers such as Boethius and Martianus Capella. Notker is also attributed the authorship of five short essays on music.[1] La...
L'équipe d'Angleterre a remporté la Coupe du monde de rugby 2003, après avoir battu l'équipe d'Australie lors de la finale. L'Angleterre commence la Coupe du monde 2003 à Subiaco Oval et s'impose 84 à 6 contre la Géorgie[1]. Wilkinson marque 20 des 25 points de l'équipe lors du match contre les Springboks, assurant la victoire 25 à 6[2]. Le match contre les Samoa est remporté 35 à 22[3]. Enfin, l'Angleterre s'impose 111 à 13 contre l'Uruguay[4], match que Wilkinson ne dispute pas,...
منظمة بدر البلد العراق التأسيس تاريخ التأسيس 1982–2003 (1982–2003) كجناح عسكري للمجلس الأعلى الإسلامي العراقي 2003–حزب سياسي يترأسه الامين العام هادي العامري المؤسسون محمد باقر الحكيم وأحمد الخفاجي الشخصيات قائد الحزب هادي العامري القادة أبو مريم الانصاري - أحمد الخفاجي - ...
Questa voce o sezione sull'argomento hockey su ghiaccio non è ancora formattata secondo gli standard. Contribuisci a migliorarla secondo le convenzioni di Wikipedia. Segui i suggerimenti del progetto di riferimento. Stagione 2006-2007CampionatoCampionato italiano Sport Hockey su ghiaccio Numero squadre9 serie A9 serie A2 Stagione regolarePrima classificata Bolzano Finale scudettoCampione italiano Cortina Finalista Milano Vipers ← 2005-2006 2007-2008 → Ingaggi...
Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!