Reserve army of labour is a concept in Karl Marx's critique of political economy.[1] It refers to the unemployed and underemployed in capitalist society. It is synonymous with "industrial reserve army" or "relative surplus population", except that the unemployed can be defined as those actually looking for work and that the relative surplus population also includes people unable to work. The use of the word "army" refers to the workers being conscripted and regimented in the workplace in a hierarchy under the command or authority of the owners of capital.
Marx did not invent the term "reserve army of labour". It was already being used by Friedrich Engels in his 1845 book The Condition of the Working Class in England.[2] What Marx did was theorize the reserve army of labour as a necessary part of the capitalist organization of work.
Prior to what Marx regarded as the start of the capitalist era in human history (i.e. before the 16th century), structural unemployment on a mass scale rarely existed, other than that caused by natural disasters and wars.[3] In ancient societies, all people who could work necessarily had to work, otherwise they would starve; and a slave or a serf by definition could not become "unemployed". There was normally very little possibility of "earning a crust" without working at all, and the usual attitude toward beggars and idlers was harsh.[4] Children began to work at a very early age.
Marx's discussion of the concept
Although the idea of the industrial reserve army of labour is closely associated with Marx, it was already in circulation in the British labour movement by the 1830s.[5] Engels discussed the reserve army of labour in his famous book The Condition of the Working Class in England (1845) before Marx did. The first mention of the reserve army of labour in Marx's writing occurs in a manuscript he wrote in 1847, but did not publish:
Big industry constantly requires a reserve army of unemployed workers for times of overproduction. The main purpose of the bourgeois in relation to the worker is, of course, to have the commodity labour as cheaply as possible, which is only possible when the supply of this commodity is as large as possible in relation to the demand for it, i.e., when the overpopulation is the greatest. Overpopulation is therefore in the interest of the bourgeoisie, and it gives the workers good advice which it knows to be impossible to carry out. Since capital only increases when it employs workers, the increase of capital involves an increase of the proletariat, and, as we have seen, according to the nature of the relation of capital and labour, the increase of the proletariat must proceed relatively even faster. The above theory, however, which is also expressed as a law of nature, that population grows faster than the means of subsistence, is the more welcome to the bourgeois as it silences his conscience, makes hard-heartedness into a moral duty and the consequences of society into the consequences of nature, and finally gives him the opportunity to watch the destruction of the proletariat by starvation as calmly as any other natural event without bestirring himself, and, on the other hand, to regard the misery of the proletariat as its own fault and to punish it. To be sure, the proletarian can restrain his natural instinct by reason, and so, by moral supervision, halt the law of nature in its injurious course of development.
The idea of the labour force as an "army" occurs also in Part 1 of The Communist Manifesto, written by Marx and Engels in 1848:
Modern Industry has converted the little workshop of the patriarchal master into the great factory of the industrial capitalist. Masses of labourers, crowded into the factory, are organised like soldiers. As privates of the industrial army they are placed under the command of a perfect hierarchy of officers and sergeants. Not only are they slaves of the bourgeois class, and of the bourgeois State; they are daily and hourly enslaved by the machine, by the overlooker, and, above all, by the individual bourgeois manufacturer himself. The more openly this despotism proclaims gain to be its end and aim, the more petty, the more hateful and the more embittering it is.
Marx introduces the concept of the reserve army of labour in chapter 25 of the first volume of Capital: Critique of Political Economy,[7] twenty years later in 1867, stating the following:
[...] capitalistic accumulation itself [...] constantly produces, and produces in the direct ratio of its own energy and extent, a relatively redundant population of workers, i.e., a population of greater extent than suffices for the average needs of the valorisation of capital, and therefore a surplus-population... It is the absolute interest of every capitalist to press a given quantity of labour out of a smaller, rather than a greater number of labourers, if the cost is about the same. [...] The more extended the scale of production, the stronger this motive. Its force increases with the accumulation of capital.
His argument is that as capitalism develops, the organic composition of capital will increase, which means that the mass of constant capital grows faster than the mass of variable capital. Fewer workers can produce all that is necessary for society's requirements. In addition, capital will become more concentrated and centralized in fewer hands.
This being the absolute historical tendency under capitalism, part of the working population will tend to become surplus to the requirements of capital accumulation over time. Paradoxically, the larger the wealth of society, the larger the industrial reserve army will become. One could add that the larger the wealth of society, the more people it can also support who do not work.
However, as Marx develops the argument further it also becomes clear that depending on the state of the economy, the reserve army of labour will either expand or contract, alternately being absorbed or expelled from the employed workforce:
Taking them as a whole, the general movements of wages are exclusively regulated by the expansion and contraction of the industrial reserve army, and these again correspond to the periodic changes of the industrial cycle. They are, therefore, not determined by the variations of the absolute number of the working population, but by the varying proportions in which the working-class is divided into active and reserve army, by the increase or diminution in the relative amount of the surplus-population, by the extent to which it is now absorbed, now set free.
Marx concludes as such: "Relative surplus-population is therefore the pivot upon which the law of demand and supply of labour works". The availability of labour influences wage rates and the larger the unemployed workforce grows, the more this forces down wage rates; conversely, if there are plenty jobs available and unemployment is low, this tends to raise the average level of wages—in that case workers are able to change jobs rapidly to get better pay.
Composition of the relative surplus population
Marx discusses the army of labor and the reserve army in Capital Volume I, Chapter 25, Section IV. The army of labor consists in those working class people employed in average or better than average jobs. Not every one in the working class gets one of these jobs. There are then four other categories where members of the working class might find themselves: the stagnant pool, the floating reserves, the latent reserve and pauperdom. Finally, people may leave the army and the reserve army by turning to criminality, Marx refers to such people as lumpenproletariat.[8]
The stagnant part consists of marginalised people with "extremely irregular employment". Stagnant pool jobs are characterized by below average pay, dangerous working conditions and they may be temporary. Those caught in the stagnant pool have jobs, so the modern definition of the employed would include both the army of labor plus the stagnant pool. However, they are constantly on the lookout for something better.
The modern unemployed would refer primarily to the floating reserve, people who used to have good jobs, but are now out of work. They certainly hope that their unemployment is temporary ("conjunctural unemployment"), but they are well aware that they could fall into the stagnant pool or the pauper class.
The latent part consists of that segment of the population not yet fully integrated into capitalist production. In Marx's day, he was referring to people living off of subsistence agriculture who were looking for monetary employment in industry. In modern times, people coming from slums in developing countries where they survive largely by non-monetary means, to developed cities where they work for pay might form the latent.[clarification needed] Housewives who move from unpaid to paid employment for a business could also form a part of the latent reserve. They are not unemployed because they are not necessarily actively looking for a job, but if capital needs extra workers, it can pull them out of the latent reserve. In this sense, the latent forms a reservoir of potential workers for industries.
Pauperdom is where one might end up. The homeless is the modern term for paupers. Marx calls them people who cannot adapt to capital's never ending change. For Marx, "the sphere of pauperism", including those still able to work, orphans and pauper children and the "demoralised and ragged" or "unable to work".
Marx then analyses the reserve army of labour in detail using data on Britain where he lived.
Some economists such as Paul Samuelson have taken issue with Marx's concept of the reserve army of labour. Samuelson argues that much Marxian literature assumes that the mere existence of the unemployed drives down wages, when in reality is dependent upon contingent factors. (Are the unemployed easily available as replacements? Is the mere threat of replacement sufficient to get workers to accept a wage cut or does the employer have to demonstrate this is not an empty threat?) Samuelson argues that if prices also fall with money wage, then this does not mean real wages will fall. Samuelson also argues that wages will fall only until there are no more unemployed to bid it down: the reserve army can reduce wages only by decreasing its size. Samuelson's concludes that to mean that while the unemployed can reduce wages, they are incapable of reducing them to anywhere near subsistence levels before the unemployed all become employed.[9]
A similar argument was made by Murray Rothbard, who argued that if the reserve army lower wages by being absorbed into the ranks of the employed, then eventually it will disappear and be incapable of being a threat (that also means that the risk of perpetual impoverishment is averted). Rothbard observes that this is supported by modern market economics, which holds that unemployment lowers wages and thus ultimately eliminates itself. Thus, Rothbard concludes that the reserve army would ultimately cease to be a threat. Rothbard also argues that industries can experience an increase in demand for other works thanks to increasing productivity caused by technology, which will then decrease unemployment due to a greater demand for workers caused by expanding production capability.[10]
Immiseration
Some writers have interpreted Marx's argument to mean that an absolute immiseration of the working class would occur as the broad historical trend. Thus, the workers would become more and more impoverished and unemployment would constantly grow.[11] This is no longer credible in the light of the facts because in various epochs and countries workers' living standards have indeed improved rather than declined. In some periods, unemployment had been reduced to a very small amount. In the Great Depression, about one in four workers became unemployed, but towards the end of the post-war boom unemployment in richer countries reduced to a very low level. However, economic historian Paul Bairoch estimated in the mid-1980s that in Latin America, Africa and Asia "total inactivity" among the population was "on the order of 30-40% of potential working man-hours"—a situation without historical precedent, "except perhaps in the case of ancient Rome".[12]
Other writers, such as Ernest Mandel and Roman Rosdolsky,[13][14] argued that in truth Marx had no theory of an absolute immiseration of the working class; at most, one could say that the rich-poor gap continues to grow, i.e. the wealthy get wealthier much more than ordinary workers improve their living standards. In part, the level of unemployment also seems to be based on the balance of power between social classes and state policy. Governments can allow unemployment to rise, but also implement job-creating policies, which makes unemployment levels partly a political result.
If chapter 25 of Marx's Capital, Volume I is read carefully, it is plain that Marx does not actually say what many critics accuse him of.[15] Marx himself says that the "absolute general law of capitalist accumulation" is that the more that capital grows in size and value, the bigger the working class becomes and the larger the pauperized sections of the working class and the industrial reserve army become.[16] However, he does not say that the whole working class becomes pauperized, but rather that the part of it which is pauperized grows in size. He then carefully qualifies this argument by saying that the absolute general law is "like all other laws [...] modified in its working by many circumstances".[16] Next, Marx says that in proportion as capital accumulates, the situation of the worker, be his payment high or low must "grow worse".[17] It is quite clear from the context though that by "worse" Marx does not primarily mean poverty. He means instead, as he says himself explicitly, that "all means of development of production undergo a dialectical inversion so that they become means of domination and exploitation of the producers".[17] He is talking about "worse" in the sense of "inhuman", "more exploited" or "alienated".
Overpopulation
Another dispute concerns the notion of "overpopulation".[18] In Marx's own time, Thomas Robert Malthus raised dire predictions that population growth enabled by capitalist wealth would exceed the food supply required to sustain that population. As noted, for Marx "overpopulation" was really more an ideologicallyloaded term or social construct and Marxists have argued there is no real problem here as enough food can be produced for all; if there is a problem, it lies in the way that food is produced and distributed.
Consent
In the social welfare area, there are also perpetual disputes about the extent to which unemployment is voluntarily chosen by people, or involuntary, whether it is forced on people or whether it is their own choice.[19] In the Great Depression of the 1930s, when unemployment rose to 20–30% of the working population in many countries, people generally believed it was involuntary, but if unemployment levels are relatively low, the argument that unemployment is a matter of choice is more often heard.[20]
Measurement
There are endless debates about the best way to measure unemployment, its costs and its effects and to what extent a degree of unemployment is inevitable in any country with a developed labour market.[21] According to the NAIRU concept, price stability in market-based societies necessarily requires a certain amount of unemployment. One reason a reserve army of the unemployed exists in market economies, it is argued, is that if the level of unemployment is too low, it will stimulate price inflation. However, the validity of this argument depends also on state economic policy and on the ability of workers to raise their wages. If for example trade unions are legally blocked from organizing workers, then even if unemployment is relatively low, average wages can be kept low; the only way that individual workers have in that case to raise their income is to work more hours or work themselves up to better-paying jobs.
Normally, the government measure of unemployment defines "unemployed" as "without any job, but actively looking for work". There are also people defined as "jobless", who want work yet are not, or no longer, actively looking for work because they are discouraged and so on. This official view of the matter is closely linked to the administration of unemployment benefits. To be entitled for an unemployment benefit, it is a requirement that the beneficiary is actively looking for work.
Hidden unemployment
There are also many controversies about hidden unemployment. Hidden unemployment means that people are not counted or considered as unemployed, although in reality they are unemployed. For example, young people will stay in the family home, in schooling, or in some make-work scheme because they can not find a paid job. People might also have a job, but they might be underemployed because they cannot get more working hours or they cannot get a job for which they are qualified. People might also drop out of the official labour force because they are discouraged and no longer actively looking for work; they are no longer counted as unemployed, although they are. Governments can also subsidize employment of people who would otherwise be unemployed, or put people on benefits even although they could be working. It may be that workers are hired, but that they do nothing while at work.[citation needed]
On the one side, governments often try to make unemployment seem as low as possible because that is politically desirable. On the other side, governments also often provide "broader" and "narrower" measures of unemployment. For example, the United States Bureau of Labor Statistics provides six measures of labor underutilization (U-1 through U-6). The U-3 rate is the "official" unemployment rate.
Global reserve army of labour
Marx was writing in the mid-19th century, and his discussion of unemployment may therefore be in part out of date, especially if one considers only particular developed countries. However, his analysis may continue to be quite valid if considered globally.[22] The ILO reports that the proportion of jobless has been steadily increasing since the beginning of the financial crisis of 2007–2008.
In 2007, the ILO standard global unemployment measure stood at 169.7 million. In 2012, the ILO global unemployment rate reached 5.9% of the civilian labour force (195.4 million, or a net 25.7 million more), 0.5 percentage points higher than the 5.4% rate before the financial crisis. The official global unemployment rate was expected to have risen to 6% of the civilian labour force in 2013. Over 30 million jobs were still needed to return total employment to the level that prevailed before the financial crisis. It was expected in 2013 that globally about 205 million people would be unemployed in 2014 and 214 million in 2018.[23] However, the official total of the unemployed was subsequently (in 2017) forecast to be just over 201 million persons in that year and with an additional rise of 2.7 million expected in 2018.[24] The official world total of unemployed in the labour force is approximately equal to the total number of employed workers in the United States, Canada and Mexico put together.
The official unemployment figures do not include jobless people who have dropped out of the labour force altogether because they can not find work as they include only those actually looking for work. The global unemployment rate is strongly influenced by population growth; the more population, the more unemployed and employed in absolute numbers. However, the proportion of jobless people now rises every year and is expected to continue rising for quite some time.
Among the world's unemployed, the ILO estimates that roughly half the global total are young people aged 15 to 24. In the rich countries, it often does not matter so much if young people are unemployed at that age, but in the Middle East, Asia, Africa and Latin America where most of the unemployed youths are it is often a much more serious problem.[25]
Modern academic usage
In recent years, there has been a growing use in Marxist and anarchist theory of the concept of "the precariat" to describe a growing reliance on temporary, part-time workers with precarious status who share aspects of the proletariat and the reserve army of labor.[26] Precarious workers do work part-time or full-time in temporary jobs, but they cannot really earn enough to live on and depend partly on friends or family, or on state benefits, to survive. Typically, they do not become truly "unemployed", but they do not have a decent job to go to either.[27]
Although non-employed people who are unable or uninterested in performing legal paid work are not considered among the "unemployed", the concept of "conjunctural unemployment" is used in economics nowadays.[28] Economists often distinguish between short-term "frictional" or "cyclical" unemployment and longer-term "structural unemployment". Sometimes there is a shortterm mismatch between the demand and supply of labour, at other times there is much less total demand for labour than supply for a long time. If there is no possibility for getting a job at all in the foreseeable future, many younger people decide to emigrate to a place where they can find work.
^Francis Green, "The Reserve Army Hypothesis: A Survey of Empirical Applications," in Paul Dunne (ed.), Quantitative Marxism, Cambridge: Polity Press, 1991, pp. 123–140.
^Denning, Michael (2010). "Wageless life". New Left Review. 66: 79–97.
^"Wages", Works of Karl Marx 1847; Source: MECW Volume 6, p. 415; Written: at the end of December 1847; First published: in Russian in the journal Sotsialisticheskoye khozyaistvo, 1924 and in German in the journal Unter dem Banner des Marxismus, 1925.
^Rothbard, Murray, An Austrian Perspective on the History of Economic Thought: Classical economics, Ludwig von Mises Institute, 2006, pp.424-425
^Thomas Sowell, "Marx's 'increasing misery' doctrine", American Economic Review, L, No. 1, March 1960, pp. 111–120.Thomas Sowell, Marxism: philosophy and economics. London: George Allen & Unwin, 1985, chapter 10.
^Paul Bairoch, Cities and Economic Development. From the Dawn of History to the Present. London: Mansell, 1988, p. 466.
^E. Germain [pseud. Ernest Mandel] (February 1957). "Gibt es eine Marx'sche Verelendungstheorie?". Die Internationale. 3: 25–35. ISSN0535-4005.
^de Vroey, Michel (2004). Involuntary Unemployment: The Elusive Quest for a Theory. London: Routledge. ISBN978-0-415-08074-3.
^Brass, Tom; Van Der Linden, Marcel, eds. (1997). Free and Unfree Labour: The Debate Continues. International and Comparative Social History. Vol. 5. New York: Peter Lang. ISBN978-0-8204-3424-7.
يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم في تطوير هذه المقالة من خلال إضافة مصادر موثوق بها. أي معلومات غير موثقة يمكن التشكيك بها وإزالتها. (ديسمبر 2018) بطولة الأندية الآسيوية 1967تفاصيل المسابقةالتواريخ5 مايو – 19 ديسمبر 1967الفرق6المراكز النهائيةالبطل هبوعيل
Yohanes 4Berkas:Alkitab tb yohanes3 besar.jpgHalaman-halaman yang memuat Yohanes pasal 3 dan 4 dalam Alkitab bahasa Indonesia versi Terjemahan BaruKitabInjil YohanesKategoriInjilBagian Alkitab KristenPerjanjian BaruUrutan dalamKitab Kristen4← pasal 3 pasal 5 → Yohanes 4 (disingkat Yoh 4) adalah bagian dari Injil Yohanes pada Perjanjian Baru dalam Alkitab Kristen, menurut kesaksian Yohanes, seorang dari Keduabelas Rasul pertama Yesus Kristus.[1][2] Teks Teks Yohanes...
هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (أبريل 2019) سامانثا ولز معلومات شخصية الميلاد 2 أغسطس 1989 (34 سنة) واراتاه [لغات أخرى] مواطنة أستراليا الطول 165 سنتيمتر[1] الوزن 63 كيلوغرام[1]...
Head of state of the Czech Republic President of the RepublicPrezident republikyPresidential StandardIncumbentPetr Pavelsince 9 March 2023Head of state of the Czech RepublicStyleHis ExcellencyTypeHead of stateResidencePrague CastleSeatPrague, Czech RepublicAppointerPopular voteTerm lengthFive years, renewable once consecutivelyConstituting instrumentConstitution of the Czech RepublicPrecursorPresident of Czechoslovakia Formation2 February 1993; 30 years ago (1993-02-02)...
Wooden horse used to win the Trojan War This article is about the mythological Trojan Horse. For the type of malware, see Trojan horse (computing). For other uses, see Trojan horse (disambiguation). Trojan WarAchilles tending the wounded Patroclus(Attic red-figure kylix, c. 500 BC) Literary sources Iliad Epic Cycle Aeneid, Book 2 Iphigenia in Aulis Philoctetes Ajax The Trojan Women Posthomerica See also: Trojan War in literature and the arts Episodes Judgement of Paris Seduction of Helen Troj...
Wapen van de familie de Walckiers De Walckiers was een Zuid-Nederlandse familie van wie telgen in de Oostenrijkse Nederlanden en in het koninkrijk België in de erfelijke adel werden opgenomen. Geschiedenis In 1727 verleende keizer Karel VI erfelijke adel aan Cornelius de Walckiers. In 1747 verleende dezelfde keizer erfelijke adel aan Jean Josse de Walckiers, voorvader van de hierna genoemden. In 1786 verleende keizer Jozef II de titel burggraaf aan Adrien de Walckiers de Tronchienne (1721-17...
Division of the lifetime of the cosmos A cosmological decade (CÐ) is a division of the lifetime of the cosmos. The divisions are logarithmic in size, with base 10. Each successive cosmological decade represents a ten-fold increase in the total age of the universe.[1] As expressed in log (seconds per Ðecade) When CÐ is measured in log( seconds/Ð ), CÐ 1 begins at 10 seconds and lasts 90 seconds (until 100 seconds after Time Zero). CÐ 100, the 100th cosmologica...
Gereja Kristus Rahmani IndonesiaLogo GKRIPenggolonganProtestanPemimpinPdt. Prof. DR. S.J. SutjionoWilayahIndonesiaDidirikan12 Desember 1971 Jakarta, IndonesiaSitus web resmiSinode GKRIEmail: sinodegkri@yahoo.co.id Gereja Kristus Rahmani Indonesia (disingkat GKRI) ialah sebuah kelompok gereja Kristen Protestan di Indonesia dengan Pdt. Prof. DR. S.J. Sutjiono sebagai pendirinya, yaitu yang merintis GKRI sejak tahun 1971. Kebaktian pertama kali GKRI diadakan pada tanggal 12 Desember 1971 di Jaka...
United States historic placeDecatur County CourthouseU.S. National Register of Historic Places Show map of IowaShow map of the United StatesLocation9th St.Leon, IowaCoordinates40°44′26″N 93°44′46″W / 40.74056°N 93.74611°W / 40.74056; -93.74611Arealess than one acreBuilt1908ArchitectSmith, Wetherell and GageArchitectural styleRenaissance RevivalMPSCounty Courthouses in Iowa TRNRHP reference No.81000233[1]Added to NRHPJuly 2, 1981 The D...
هذه المقالة عن أغاثون الأول، بابا الإسكندرية وبطريرك الكرازة المرقسية في القرن السابع الميلادي. لأغاثو، بابا الكنيسة الكاثوليكية المعاصر له، طالع أغاثو (بابا). أغاثون الأول معلومات شخصية الميلاد القرن 7 مصر الوفاة 13 أكتوبر 680 مصر مكان الدفن الكاتدرائية ...
Artikel ini membutuhkan rujukan tambahan agar kualitasnya dapat dipastikan. Mohon bantu kami mengembangkan artikel ini dengan cara menambahkan rujukan ke sumber tepercaya. Pernyataan tak bersumber bisa saja dipertentangkan dan dihapus.Cari sumber: Fantasmagorie film 1908 – berita · surat kabar · buku · cendekiawan · JSTOR (February 2022) FantasmagorieSutradara Émile Cohl Produser Émile Cohl Ditulis olehDistributorSociété des Etablissements L. ...
AltaiteSilvery veins and flecks of altaite throughout the matrix from the Hilltop Mine, Organ District, Doña Ana County, New Mexico (size: 3.5 x 2.9 x 1.9 cm)GeneralCategoryTelluride mineralFormula(repeating unit)PbTeIMA symbolAlt[1]Strunz classification2.CD.10Crystal systemIsometricCrystal classHexoctahedral (m3m) H-M symbol: (4/m 3 2/m)Space groupFm3mIdentificationFormula mass334.8 g/molColortin white to yellowish white; tarnishing to bronze yellowCrystal habitinclude cubic and oct...
Pride parades in Poland Warsaw Equality Parade in 2018 Equality marches or equality parades (Polish: marsze równości; parady równości) are the Polish equivalent of pride parades,[1] which aim to improve LGBT rights in Poland. They have been held in various Polish cities and towns since 2001.[2] Equality marches in Poland 2001-2023 Overview See also: LGBT history in Poland Counter-protesters against the 2006 Equality Parade in Warsaw In 2007 (Bączkowski v Poland), the 2005...
German businessman (1921–1967) This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Harald Quandt – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (December 2018) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Harald QuandtIn a vintage manipulated image,[1] Quandt (in Luftwaffe Fahnenjunker uniform a...
American politician Edward J. KasemeyerEdward J. Kasemeyer (2009)Member of the Maryland SenateIn officeJanuary 11, 1995 – January 9, 2019Preceded byNancy L. MurphySucceeded byClarence K. LamConstituency12th districtIn officeJanuary 14, 1987 – January 1991Preceded byJames Clark Jr.Succeeded byChristopher J. McCabeConstituency14th districtMember of the Maryland House of Delegates from District 14BIn officeJanuary 12, 1983 – January 14, 1987Serving with R...
Slang term For other uses, see Bimbo (disambiguation). Presumed portrait of Rosalie Duthé (1748–1830), called the first officially recorded dumb blonde. Bimbo is slang for a conventionally attractive, sexualized, naive, and unintelligent woman.[1] The term was originally used in the United States as early as 1919 for an unintelligent or brutish man.[2] As of the early 21st century, the stereotypical bimbo appearance became that of an attractive woman. It is often used to de...
Highway in Maine Interstate 395I-395 highlighted in redRoute informationAuxiliary route of I-95Maintained by MaineDOTLength4.99 mi[1] (8.03 km)NHSEntire routeMajor junctionsWest end US 2 / SR 100 in BangorMajor intersections I-95 / SR 15 in Bangor US 1A / US 202 / SR 9 in Bangor East end US 1A in Brewer LocationCountryUnited StatesStateMaineCountiesPenobscot Highway system Interstate Highway System Main Au...
Supercopa Xerox 1996ゼロックス スーパーカップ1996 III Supercopa de Japón El Estadio Nacional de Tokio, sede de la final.Datos generalesSede Japón JapónCategoría Primera DivisiónFecha 9 de marzo de 1996Edición 3.ªOrganizador J. LeaguePalmarésCampeón Nagoya Grampus EightSubcampeón Yokohama MarinosDatos estadísticosAsistentes 39 570Participantes 2 equipos Cronología 1995 1996 1997 [editar datos en Wikidata] La Supercopa de Japón 1996, también conocida com...
Honda ActyInformasiProdusenHondaMasa produksi1977–sekarangBodi & rangkaKelasMicrovan truk keiBentuk kerangka5-door Van2-door truk pikapTata letakMesin tengah, penggerak roda belakang/ 4WD.Mobil terkaitHonda VamosKronologiPendahuluHonda TN7 (truk)Honda Life (van) Honda Acty adalah microvan dan truk kei yang diproduksi oleh Honda yang didesain untuk pasar domestik Jepang. Acty bersaing dengan Subaru Sambar, Suzuki Carry, Daihatsu Hijet, dan Mitsubishi Minicab. Referensi Pranala luar ...