Profit (economics)

Difference between how accountants and economists view a firm

In economics, profit is the difference between revenue that an economic entity has received from its outputs and total costs of its inputs, also known as surplus value.[1] It is equal to total revenue minus total cost, including both explicit and implicit costs.[2]

It is different from accounting profit, which only relates to the explicit costs that appear on a firm's financial statements. An accountant measures the firm's accounting profit as the firm's total revenue minus only the firm's explicit costs. An economist includes all costs, both explicit and implicit costs, when analyzing a firm. Therefore, economic profit is smaller than accounting profit.[3]

Normal profit is often viewed in conjunction with economic profit. Normal profits in business refer to a situation where a company generates revenue that is equal to the total costs incurred in its operation, thus allowing it to remain operational in a competitive industry. It is the minimum profit level that a company can achieve to justify its continued operation in the market where there is competition. In order to determine if a company has achieved normal profit, they first have to calculate their economic profit. If the company's total revenue is equal to its total costs, then its economic profit is equal to zero and the company is in a state of normal profit. Normal profit occurs when resources are being used in the most efficient way at the highest and best use. Normal profit and economic profit are economic considerations while accounting profit refers to the profit a company reports on its financial statements each period.

Normal profit = Total revenue – Total costs
Normal profit = Revenues – Total costs
Normal profit = Revenues – (Implicit costs + Explicit costs)

Economic profits arise in markets which are non-competitive and have significant barriers to entry, i.e. monopolies and oligopolies. The inefficiencies and lack of competition in these markets foster an environment where firms can set prices or quantities instead of being price-takers, which is what occurs in a perfectly competitive market.[4] In a perfectly competitive market when long-run economic equilibrium is reached, economic profit would become non-existent, because there is no incentive for firms either to enter or to leave the industry.[5]

Competitive and contestable markets

Only in the short run can a firm in a perfectly competitive market make an economic profit.

Companies do not make any economic profits in a perfectly competitive market once it has reached a long run equilibrium. If an economic profit was available, there would be an incentive for new firms to enter the industry, aided by a lack of barriers to entry, until it no longer existed.[6] When new firms enter the market, the overall supply increases. Furthermore, these intruders are forced to offer their product at a lower price to entice consumers to buy the additional supply they have created and to compete with the incumbent firms (see Monopoly profit § Persistence).[7][8][9][10] As the incumbent firms within the industry face losing their existing customers to the new entrants,[11] they are also forced to reduce their prices. Therefore, increased competition reduces price and cost to the minimum of the long run average costs. At this point, price equals both the marginal cost and the average total cost for each good production.[7][8] Once this has occurred a perfect competition exists and economic profit is no longer available.[12] When this occurs, economic agents outside the industry find no advantage to entering the market, as there is no economic profit to be gained. Then, the supply of the product stops increasing, and the price charged for the product stabilizes, settling into an equilibrium.[7][8][9]

The same is likewise true of the long run equilibria of monopolistically competitive industries, and more generally any market which is held to be contestable. Normally, a firm that introduces a differentiated product can initially secure temporary market power for a short while (See Monopoly Profit § Persistence). At this stage, the initial price the consumer must pay for the product is high, and the demand for, as well as the availability of the product in the market, will be limited. In the long run however, when the profitability of the product is well established, and because there are few barriers to entry,[7][8][9] the number of firms that produce this product will increase. Eventually, the supply of the product will become relatively large, and the price of the product will reduce to the level of the average cost of production. When this finally occurs, all economic profit associated with producing and selling the product disappears, and the initial monopoly turns into a competitive industry.[7][8][9] In the case of contestable markets, the cycle is often ended with the departure of the former "hit and run" entrants to the market, returning the industry to its previous state, just with a lower price and no economic profit for the incumbent firms.

Economic profit can, however, occur in competitive and contestable markets in the short run, since short run economic profits attract new competitors and prices fall. Economic loss forces firms out of the industry and prices rise till marginal revenue equals marginal cost, then reach long run equilibrium. As a result of firms jostling for market position. Once risk is accounted for, long-lasting economic profit in a competitive market is thus viewed as the result of constant cost-cutting and performance improvement ahead of industry competitors, allowing costs to be below the market-set price.

Uncompetitive markets

A monopolist can set a price in excess of costs, making an economic profit (shaded). The above picture shows a monopolist (only one firm in the industry/market) that obtains a (monopoly) economic profit. An oligopoly usually has "economic profit" also, but usually faces an industry/market with more than just one firm (they must share available demand at the market price).

Economic profit is much more prevalent in uncompetitive markets such as in a perfect monopoly or oligopoly situation, where few substitutes exit. In these scenarios, individual firms have some element of market power. Although monopolists are constrained by consumer demand, they are not price takers, but instead either price or quantity setters. Due to the output effect and the price effect, marginal revenue for uncompetitive markets is very different from marginal revenue for competitive firms.[13] In the output effect, more output is sold, quantity sold is higher. In the price effect, this reduces the prices firms charge for every unit they sell, and cut in price reduces revenue on the units it was already selling. Therefore, in uncompetitive market, marginal revenue is less than its price. This allows the firm to set a price which is higher than that which would be found in a similar but more competitive industry, allowing the firms to maintain an economic profit in both the short and long run.[7][8]

The existence of economic profits depends on the prevalence of barriers to entry, which stop other firms from entering into the industry and sapping away profits like they would in a more competitive market.[10] Examples of barriers to entry include patents, land rights, and certain zoning laws.[14] These barriers allow firms to maintain a large portion of market share due to new entrants being unable to obtain the necessary requirements or pay the initial costs of entry.

An oligopoly is a case where barriers are present, but more than one firm is able to maintain the majority of the market share. In an oligopoly, firms are able to collude and limit production, thereby restricting supply and maintaining a constant economic profit.[7][10][2] An extreme case of an uncompetitive market is a monopoly, where only one firm has the ability to supply a good which has no close substitutes.[14] In this case, the monopolist can set its price at any level it desires, maintaining a substantial economic profit. In both scenarios, firms are able to maintain an economic profit by setting prices well above the costs of production, receiving an income that is significantly more than its implicit and explicit costs.

Government intervention

The existence of uncompetitive markets puts consumers at risk of paying substantially higher prices for lower quality products.[15] When monopolies and oligopolies hold large portions of the market share, less emphasis is placed on consumer demand than there would be in a perfectly competitive market, especially if the good provided has an inelastic demand. Government intervention in the form of restrictions and subsidies can also create uncompetitive markets.[16] Governments can also intervene in uncompetitive markets in an attempt to raise the number of firms in the industry, but these firms cannot support the needs of consumers as if they were born out of a profit generated on a competitive market basis.[17] [neutrality is disputed]

In a regulated industry, the government examines firms' marginal cost structure and allows them to charge a price that is no greater than this marginal cost. This does not necessarily ensure zero economic profit for the firm, but eliminates a monopoly profit.

Competition laws were created to prevent powerful firms from using their economic power to artificially create barriers to entry in an attempt to protect their economic profits.[8][9][10] This includes the use of predatory pricing toward smaller competitors.[7][10][2] For example, in the United States, Microsoft Corporation was initially convicted of breaking Anti-Trust Law and engaging in anti-competitive behaviour in order to form one such barrier in United States v. Microsoft. After a successful appeal on technical grounds, Microsoft agreed to a settlement with the Department of Justice in which they were faced with stringent oversight procedures and explicit requirements[18] designed to prevent this predatory behaviour. With lower barriers, new firms can enter into the market again, making the long run equilibrium much more like that of a competitive industry, with no economic profit for firms and more reasonable prices for consumers.

On the other hand, if a government feels it is impractical to have a competitive market—such as in the case of a natural monopoly—it will allow a monopolistic market to occur. The government will regulate the existing uncompetitive market and control the price the firms charge for their product.[8][9] For example, the old AT&T (regulated) monopoly, which existed before the courts ordered its breakup, had to get government approval to raise its prices. The government examined the monopoly's costs, and determined whether or not the monopoly should be able raise its price. If the government felt that the cost did not justify a higher price, it rejected the monopoly's application for a higher price. Though a regulated firm will not have an economic profit as large as it would in an unregulated situation, it can still make profits well above a competitive firm in a truly competitive market.[9]

Maximization

It is a standard economic assumption (although not necessarily a perfect one in the real world) that, other things being equal, a firm will attempt to maximize its profits.[19] Given that profit is defined as the difference in total revenue and total cost, a firm achieves its maximum profit by operating at the point where the difference between the two is at its greatest. The goal of maximizing profit is also what leads firms to enter markets where economic profit exists, with the main focus being to maximize production without significantly increasing its marginal cost per good. In markets which do not show interdependence, this point can either be found by looking at these two curves directly, or by finding and selecting the best of the points where the gradients of the two curves (marginal revenue and marginal cost respectively) are equal.[14] In the real world, it is not so easy to know exactly firm's marginal revenue and the marginal cost of last goods sold. For example, it is difficult for firms to know the price elasticity of demand for their good – which determines the MR.[20] In interdependent markets, It means firm's profit also depends on how other firms react, game theory must be used to derive a profit maximizing solution.

Another significant factor for profit maximization is market fractionation. A company may sell goods in several regions or in several countries. Profit is maximized by treating each location as a separate market.[21] Rather than matching supply and demand for the entire company the matching is done within each market. Each market has different competitions, different supply constraints (like shipping) and different social factors. When the price of goods in each market area is set by each market then overall profit is maximized.

Other applications of the term

The social profit from a firm's activities is the accounting profit plus or minus any externalities or consumer surpluses that occur in its activity. An externality including positive externality and negative externality is an effect that production/consumption of a specific good exerts on people who are not involved.[7][10][2] Pollution is an example for negative externality.

Consumer surplus is an economic indicator which measures consumer benefits.[7][10][2] The price that consumers pay for a product is not greater than the price they desire to pay, and in this case there will be consumer surplus.

For the supply side of economics, the general school of thought is that profit is meant to ensure shareholder yield. While it is the case that profits are a means for shareholder returns, it also fulfills other functions. A target surplus may secure long-term solvency in the event of facing potential adversity. Capital surplus may be used to finance investments with significant capital expenditures or charitable contributions. All in all, producer surplus concerns several factors of interest for a for-profit economic entity.[22][23]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ Arnold, Roger A. (2001). Economics (5 ed.). South-Western College Publishing. p. 475. ISBN 9780324071450. Retrieved 14 April 2021. Economic profit is the difference between total revenue and total opportunity cost, including both its explicit and implicit components. [...] Economic profit = Total revenue – Total opportunity cost [...]
  2. ^ a b c d e Black, 2003.
  3. ^ Mankiw, Gregory (2013). Principles of Economics. CENGAGE Lesrning.
  4. ^ Hubbard, Glenn; O'Brien, Anthony (2014). Essentials of Economics, Global Edition (4 ed.). Pearson Education Limited. p. 397. ISBN 9781292079172.
  5. ^ Lipsey, 1975. pp. 285–59.
  6. ^ Lipsey, 1975. p. 217.
  7. ^ a b c d e f g h i j Chiller, 1991.
  8. ^ a b c d e f g h Mansfield, 1979.
  9. ^ a b c d e f g LeRoy Miller, 1982.
  10. ^ a b c d e f g Tirole, 1988.
  11. ^ Saloner, Garth (2001). Strategic Management. John Wiley. p. 216.
  12. ^ Desai, Meghnad (16 March 2017). "Profit and Profit Theory" (PDF). The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 2. pp. 1–14. doi:10.1057/978-1-349-95121-5_1319-2. ISBN 978-1-349-95121-5.
  13. ^ Mankiw, Gregory (2016). principles of economics. Cengage learning. p. 288.
  14. ^ a b c Perloff, Jeffrey (2018). Microeconomics, Global Edition (8 ed.). Harlow, United Kingdom: Pearson Education Limited. pp. 252–272. ISBN 9781292215624.
  15. ^ Pindyck, Robert; Rubinfeld, Daniel (2015). Microeconomics, Global Edition. Pearson Education Limited. p. 365. ISBN 9781292081977.
  16. ^ Winters, L.Alan (1987). "THE ECONOMIC CONSEQUENCES OF AGRICULTURAL SUPPORT - A SURVEY". OECD Economic Studies. CiteSeerX 10.1.1.412.1477.
  17. ^ Rowe, James L. (2017). "Back to Basics: Economic concepts explained" (PDF). International Monetary Fund.
  18. ^ "United States of America, Plaintiff, v. Microsoft Corporation, Defendant", Final Judgement, Civil Action No. 98-1232, 12 November 2002.
  19. ^ Hirshleifer et al., 2005. p. 160.
  20. ^ Pettinger, Tejvan (16 July 2019). "Profit Maximisation". Economics help.
  21. ^ Regional Outlook (20 May 2021). "Industry Analysis Report and Forecast, 2021 - 2027". GLOBE NEWSWIRE.
  22. ^ "'Profit' variability in for-profit and not-for-profit hospitals". Science Direct. Retrieved 2 April 2023.
  23. ^ Duménil, Gérard; Lévy, Dominique (1993). "The Economics Of The Profit Rate". Books. Ideas. Retrieved 2 April 2023.

References

Read other articles:

간체는 여기로 연결됩니다. 세포에 대해서는 간상세포 문서를 참고하십시오. 한자 발달과정 갑골문자금문전서 (대전, 소전)번체간체 서체 예서 · 해서 · 행서 · 초서 글꼴 송조체 · 명조체 · 청조체 · 고딕체 · 굴림체 · 교과서체 분류법 필획 · 필순 · 육서 · 부

 

Pelabuhan KaliangetJenisBUMNKantorpusatJl. Pelabuhan, Kecamatan Kalianget SumenepJasaJasa KepelabuhananIndukPT. Pelabuhan Indonesia III (Persero) Pelabuhan Kalianget merupakan salah satu cabang dari PT. Pelabuhan Indonesia III (Persero) atau Pelindo III yang berada di wilayah Surabaya, Jawa Timur, Indonesia. Pelabuhan Kalianget merupakan pintu gerbang perekonomian Madura Timur dan merupakan pelabuhan satu-satunya yang menghubungkan wilayah daratan Sumenep dengan wilayah pulau-pulau yang ada d...

 

Kepulauan Sulu Kepulauan Sulu adalah sebuah kepulauan di Filipina bagian barat daya. Kelompok separatis setempat menganggapnya sebagai bagian dari Bangsamoro. Bahasa ibunya ialah Bahasa Tausug dan Bahasa Sama-Bajau. Kepulauan ini merupakan salah satu dari dua jembatan darat parsial menuju pulau Borneo serta sebagai rute migrasi burung. Kepulauan Sulu juga dinamakan Banjar Kulan (Little Banjar) karena memiliki hubungan historis dengan Banjarmasin.[1][2][3][4] ...

Стаття описує спортивні активності на тимчасово окупованих територіях України. Частина цієї території анексована Російською Федерацією (АРК, Севастополь), тому спортивною активністю там російські державні структури опікуються безпосередньо. На окремих територіях Луга

 

هذه المقالة بحاجة لصندوق معلومات. فضلًا ساعد في تحسين هذه المقالة بإضافة صندوق معلومات مخصص إليها. هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (فبراير 2021) يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم

 

توماس مونتسر (بالألمانية: Thomas Müntzer)‏  معلومات شخصية الميلاد 1489 الوفاة مايو 27, 1525مولهاوزن سبب الوفاة قطع الرأس[1]  مواطنة الإمبراطورية الرومانية المقدسة  الحياة العملية المدرسة الأم جامعة لايبتزغ (1506–)  المهنة قسيس،  وثوري،  وعالم عقيدة،  وشاعر غنائي...

Pour les articles homonymes, voir De Charybde en Scylla. Représentation de Scylla sur un vase grec. James Gillray, Britannia entre Scylla and Charybdis (1793). Charybde (en grec antique Χάρυϐδις / Khárubdis, pron. : [kaʀibd] « karybde ») et Scylla sont deux monstres marins de la mythologie grecque, situés de part et d'autre d'un détroit traditionnellement identifié comme étant celui de Messine[1]. La légende est à l'origine de l'expression « tomber...

 

Species of beetle Discodon planicolle Scientific classification Domain: Eukaryota Kingdom: Animalia Phylum: Arthropoda Class: Insecta Order: Coleoptera Family: Cantharidae Genus: Discodon Species: D. planicolle Binomial name Discodon planicolle(LeConte, 1858) Discodon planicolle is a species of soldier beetle in the family Cantharidae. It is found in North America.[1][2][3] References ^ Discodon planicolle Report. Integrated Taxonomic Information System. Retrieved...

 

This is a list of U.S. states and territories by economic growth rate. This article includes a list of the 50 U.S. states, the District of Columbia, and the 5 inhabited U.S. territories sorted by economic growth — the percentage change in real GDP for the first quarter of 2019 is listed (for the 50 states and District of Columbia), using the most recent data available from the U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis.[1] The most recent data for American Samoa, Guam, the Northern Mariana Is...

2007 video game 2007 video gameFootball Manager 2008Developer(s)Sports InteractivePublisher(s)SegaSeriesFootball ManagerPlatform(s) Microsoft Windows Mac OS X Xbox 360 PlayStation Portable ReleaseWindows, Mac OS XEU: 18 October 2007[1]NA/AU: 25 October 2007Xbox 360:March 2008Genre(s)Sports managementMode(s)Single-player, Multiplayer Football Manager 2008 (also known as Worldwide Soccer Manager 2008 in North America, and Fútbol Manager 2008 in South America) is the principal title of ...

 

Canadian River-class destroyer For other ships with the same name, see HMCS Skeena. Skeena at sea History Canada NameSkeena NamesakeSkeena River Ordered6 March 1928 BuilderJohn I. Thornycroft & Company, Woolston Yard number1092 Laid down14 October 1929 Launched10 October 1930 Commissioned10 June 1931 Honours andawards Atlantic 1939–44 Normandy 1944 Biscay 1944[1] FateWrecked 25 October 1944 during a storm off Reykjavík, Iceland. BadgeBlazon Azure, out of a base invected argent,...

 

Film projection at Seaworld Orlando For the episode of the Fred Wolf Studios Teenage Mutant Ninja Turtles TV series, see Teenage Mutant Ninja Turtles (1987 TV series, season 8). Turtle TrekA sea turtle swims in the Turtle Trek exhibit.SeaWorld OrlandoCoordinates28°24′50.03″N 81°27′34.92″W / 28.4138972°N 81.4597000°W / 28.4138972; -81.4597000StatusClosedOpening dateApril 27, 2012Closing dateMarch 2020Replaced bySeaWorld Rescue Center Ride statisticsManufactu...

British princess (1709–1759) AnnePrincess RoyalPortrait by Jacopo Amigoni, c. 1734Princess consort of OrangeTenure25 March 1734 - 22 October 1751Born(1709-11-02)2 November 1709(O.S.: 22 October 1709)Herrenhausen Palace, Hanover, Electorate of Hanover, Holy Roman EmpireDied12 January 1759(1759-01-12) (aged 49)The Hague, Dutch RepublicBurial23 February 1759Nieuwe Kerk, DelftSpouse William IV, Prince of Orange ​ ​(m. 1734; died 1751)​I...

 

1987 American filmBlood FrenzyDirected byHal FreemanScreenplay byTed NewsomStory byRay Dennis StecklerStarringLisa LoringDistributed byHollywood Family VideoRelease date1987CountryUnited StatesLanguageEnglishBudget$100,000[1] Blood Frenzy is a 1987 American slasher film directed by Hal Freeman and starring Lisa Loring. Premise A psychiatrist takes a group of her patients out into the desert for a therapy session. They are stalked by a killer. Cast Wendy MacDonald as Dr. Barbara Shelle...

 

Grocery store chain based in Houston, Texas This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Rice Epicurean Markets – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (September 2008) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Rice Epicurean Markets Weslayan - 206, west of River Oaks (closed, currently a...

Human settlement in WalesNeboThe centre of Nebo village, towards the village primary school.NeboLocation within GwyneddOS grid referenceSH479505CommunityLlanllyfniPrincipal areaGwyneddCountryWalesSovereign stateUnited KingdomPost townCAERNARFONPostcode districtLL54Dialling code01286PoliceNorth WalesFireNorth WalesAmbulanceWelsh UK ParliamentArfonSenedd Cymru – Welsh ParliamentArfon List of places UK Wales Gwynedd 53°01′48″N 4°16′08″W / &#...

 

В Википедии есть статьи о других людях с такой фамилией, см. Голубовский. Ян Голубовский Позиция защитник Рост 192 см Вес 95 кг Хват правый Страна  Россия Дата рождения 9 марта 1976(1976-03-09) (47 лет) Место рождения Новосибирск, РСФСР, СССР Драфт НХЛ в 1994 году был выбран в 1-м раун...

 

Indian actress AnumolBornNaduvattam, Kerala, IndiaOccupationActressYears active2010–present Anumol is an Indian actress, predominantly acting in Malayalam and Tamil films.[1] She appeared in Malayalam movies such as Chayilyam (2014), Ivan Megharoopan (2012), Akam (2011), Vedivazhipadu (2013) and Jamna Pyari (2015).Her performance as Kuruvammal in 2023 Tamil web-series Ayali applauded by Critics and Audience.[2][3][4][5][6][7] Film...

English modern soul musical collective For other uses, see Jungle (disambiguation). JungleJungle performing in Oslo in 2022Background informationOriginLondon, EnglandGenresNeo soulfunknu-discodanceYears active2013–presentLabelsCaiolaAWALXLMembers Josh Lloyd-Watson Tom McFarland Websitejunglejunglejungle.com Jungle are a British electronic music project founded in 2013 by London-based producers Josh Lloyd-Watson and Tom McFarland. Jungle have released four studio albums: Jungle (2014), which...

 

Serving in multiple public positions simultaneously For other uses, see Dual mandate (disambiguation). Double dipping redirects here. For other uses, see Double dip. A dual mandate is the practice in which elected officials serve in more than one elected or other public position simultaneously. This practice is sometimes known as double jobbing in Britain and cumul des mandats in France; not to be confused with double dipping in the United States (e.g. being employed by and receiving a retire...

 

Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!