Indifference curve

An example of an indifference map with three indifference curves represented

In economics, an indifference curve connects points on a graph representing different quantities of two goods, points between which a consumer is indifferent. That is, any combinations of two products indicated by the curve will provide the consumer with equal levels of utility, and the consumer has no preference for one combination or bundle of goods over a different combination on the same curve. One can also refer to each point on the indifference curve as rendering the same level of utility (satisfaction) for the consumer. In other words, an indifference curve is the locus of various points showing different combinations of two goods providing equal utility to the consumer. Utility is then a device to represent preferences rather than something from which preferences come.[1] The main use of indifference curves is in the representation of potentially observable demand patterns for individual consumers over commodity bundles.[2]

Indifference curve analysis is a purely technological model which cannot be used to model consumer behaviour. Every point on any given indifference curve must be satisfied by the same budget (unless the consumer can be indifferent to different budgets). As a consequence, every budget line for a given budget and any two products is tangent to the same indifference curve and this means that every budget line is tangent to, at most, one indifference curve (and so every consumer makes the same choices).

There are infinitely many indifference curves: one passes through each combination. A collection of (selected) indifference curves, illustrated graphically, is referred to as an indifference map. The slope of an indifference curve is called the MRS (marginal rate of substitution), and it indicates how much of good y must be sacrificed to keep the utility constant if good x is increased by one unit. Given a utility function u(x,y), to calculate the MRS, one takes the partial derivative of the function u with respect to good x and divide it by the partial derivative of the function u with respect to good y. If the marginal rate of substitution is diminishing along an indifference curve, that is the magnitude of the slope is decreasing or becoming less steep, then the preference is convex.

History

The theory of indifference curves was developed by Francis Ysidro Edgeworth, who explained in his 1881 book the mathematics needed for their drawing;[3] later on, Vilfredo Pareto was the first author to actually draw these curves, in his 1906 book.[4][5] The theory can be derived from William Stanley Jevons' ordinal utility theory, which posits that individuals can always rank any consumption bundles by order of preference.[6]

Map and properties

An example of how indifference curves are obtained as the level curves of a utility function

A graph of indifference curves for several utility levels of an individual consumer is called an indifference map. Points yielding different utility levels are each associated with distinct indifference curves and these indifference curves on the indifference map are like contour lines on a topographical graph. Each point on the curve represents the same elevation. If you move "off" an indifference curve traveling in a northeast direction (assuming positive marginal utility for the goods) you are essentially climbing a mound of utility. The higher you go the greater the level of utility. The non-satiation requirement means that you will never reach the "top," or a "bliss point," a consumption bundle that is preferred to all others.

Indifference curves are typically[vague] represented[clarification needed] to be:

  1. Defined only in the non-negative quadrant of commodity quantities (i.e. the possibility of having negative quantities of any good is ignored).
  2. Negatively sloped. That is, as the consumption of one good increases, to maintain constant utility, a lesser quantity of the other good just be consumed. This is equivalent to assuming Local non-satiation (an increase in the consumption of either good increases, rather than decreases, total utility). The counterfactual to this assumption is assuming a bliss point. If utility U = f(x, y), U, in the third dimension, does not have a local maximum for any x and y values.) The negative slope of the indifference curve reflects the assumption of the monotonicity of consumer's preferences, which generates monotonically increasing utility functions, and the assumption of non-satiation (marginal utility for all goods is always positive); an upward sloping indifference curve would imply that a consumer is indifferent between a bundle A and another bundle B because they lie on the same indifference curve, even in the case in which the quantity of both goods in bundle B is higher. Because of monotonicity of preferences and non-satiation, a bundle with more of both goods must be preferred to one with less of both, thus the first bundle must yield a higher utility, and lie on a different indifference curve at a higher utility level. The negative slope of the indifference curve implies that the marginal rate of substitution is always positive;
  3. Complete, such that all points on an indifference curve are ranked equally preferred and ranked either more or less preferred than every other point not on the curve. So, with (2), no two curves can intersect (otherwise non-satiation would be violated since the point(s) of intersection would have equal utility).
  4. Transitive with respect to points on distinct indifference curves. That is, if each point on I2 is (strictly) preferred to each point on I1, and each point on I3 is preferred to each point on I2, each point on I3 is preferred to each point on I1. A negative slope and transitivity exclude indifference curves crossing, since straight lines from the origin on both sides of where they crossed would give opposite and intransitive preference rankings.
  5. (Strictly) convex. Convex preferences imply that the indifference curves cannot be concave to the origin, i.e. they will either be straight lines or bulge toward the origin of the indifference curve. If the latter is the case, then as a consumer decreases consumption of one good in successive units, successively larger doses of the other good are required to keep satisfaction unchanged. Convex preferences are assumed in concordance with the principle of declining marginal utility.

Assumptions of consumer preference theory

  • Preferences are complete. The consumer has ranked all available alternative combinations of commodities in terms of the satisfaction they provide him.
Assume that there are two consumption bundles A and B each containing two commodities x and y. A consumer can unambiguously determine that one and only one of the following is the case:
  • A is preferred to B, formally written as A p B[7]
  • B is preferred to A, formally written as B p A[7]
  • A is indifferent to B, formally written as A I B[7]
This axiom precludes the possibility that the consumer cannot decide,[8] It assumes that a consumer is able to make this comparison with respect to every conceivable bundle of goods.[7]
  • Preferences are reflexive
This means that if A and B are identical in all respects the consumer will recognize this fact and be indifferent in comparing A and B
  • A = BA I B[7]
  • Preferences are transitive[nb 1]
  • If A p B and B p C, then A p C.[7]
  • Also if A I B and B I C, then A I C.[7]
This is a consistency assumption.
  • Preferences are continuous
  • If A is preferred to B and C is sufficiently close to B then A is preferred to C.
  • A p B and CBA p C.
"Continuous" means infinitely divisible - just like there are infinitely many numbers between 1 and 2 all bundles are infinitely divisible. This assumption makes indifference curves continuous.
  • Preferences exhibit strong monotonicity
  • If A has more of both x and y than B, then A is preferred to B.
This assumption is commonly called the "more is better" assumption.
An alternative version of this assumption requires that if A and B have the same quantity of one good, but A has more of the other, then A is preferred to B.

It also implies that the commodities are good rather than bad. Examples of bad commodities can be disease, pollution etc. because we always desire less of such things.

  • Indifference curves exhibit diminishing marginal rates of substitution
  • The marginal rate of substitution tells how much 'y' a person is willing to sacrifice to get one more unit of 'x'.[clarification needed]
  • This assumption assures that indifference curves are smooth and convex to the origin.
  • This assumption also set the stage for using techniques of constrained optimization because the shape of the curve assures that the first derivative is negative and the second is positive.
  • Another name for this assumption is the substitution assumption. It is the most critical assumption of consumer theory: Consumers are willing to give up or trade-off some of one good to get more of another. The fundamental assertion is that there is a maximum amount that "a consumer will give up, of one commodity, to get one unit of another good, in that amount which will leave the consumer indifferent between the new and old situations"[9] The negative slope of the indifference curves represents the willingness of the consumer to make a trade off.[9]

Application

To maximise utility, a household should consume at (Qx, Qy). Assuming it does, a full demand schedule can be deduced as the price of one good fluctuates.

Consumer theory uses indifference curves and budget constraints to generate consumer demand curves. For a single consumer, this is a relatively simple process. First, let one good be an example market e.g., carrots, and let the other be a composite of all other goods. Budget constraints give a straight line on the indifference map showing all the possible distributions between the two goods; the point of maximum utility is then the point at which an indifference curve is tangent to the budget line (illustrated). This follows from common sense: if the market values a good more than the household, the household will sell it; if the market values a good less than the household, the household will buy it. The process then continues until the market's and household's marginal rates of substitution are equal.[10] Now, if the price of carrots were to change, and the price of all other goods were to remain constant, the gradient of the budget line would also change, leading to a different point of tangency and a different quantity demanded. These price / quantity combinations can then be used to deduce a full demand curve.[10] Stated precisely, a set of indifference curve for representative of different price ratios between two goods are used to generate the Price-consumption curve in good-good vector space, which is equivalent to the demand curve in good-price vector space. The line connecting all points of tangency between the indifference curve and the budget constraint as the budget constraint changes is called the expansion path,[11] and correlates to shifts in demand. The line connecting all points of tangency between the indifference curve and budget constraint as the price of either good changes is the price-consumption curve, and correlates to movement along the demand curve.

Examples of indifference curves

In Figure 1, the consumer would rather be on I3 than I2, and would rather be on I2 than I1, but does not care where he/she is on a given indifference curve. The slope of an indifference curve (in absolute value), known by economists as the marginal rate of substitution, shows the rate at which consumers are willing to give up one good in exchange for more of the other good. For most goods the marginal rate of substitution is not constant so their indifference curves are curved. The curves are convex to the origin, describing the negative substitution effect. As price rises for a fixed money income, the consumer seeks the less expensive substitute at a lower indifference curve. The substitution effect is reinforced through the income effect of lower real income (Beattie-LaFrance). An example of a utility function that generates indifference curves of this kind is the Cobb–Douglas function . The negative slope of the indifference curve incorporates the willingness of the consumer to make trade offs.[9]

If two goods are perfect substitutes then the indifference curves will have a constant slope since the consumer would be willing to switch between at a fixed ratio. The marginal rate of substitution between perfect substitutes is likewise constant. An example of a utility function that is associated with indifference curves like these would be .

If two goods are perfect complements then the indifference curves will be L-shaped. Examples of perfect complements include left shoes compared to right shoes: the consumer is no better off having several right shoes if she has only one left shoe - additional right shoes have zero marginal utility without more left shoes, so bundles of goods differing only in the number of right shoes they include - however many - are equally preferred. The marginal rate of substitution is either zero or infinite. An example of the type of utility function that has an indifference map like that above is the Leontief function: .

The different shapes of the curves imply different responses to a change in price as shown from demand analysis in consumer theory. The results will only be stated here. A price-budget-line change that kept a consumer in equilibrium on the same indifference curve:

in Fig. 1 would reduce quantity demanded of a good smoothly as price rose relatively for that good.
in Fig. 2 would have either no effect on quantity demanded of either good (at one end of the budget constraint) or would change quantity demanded from one end of the budget constraint to the other.
in Fig. 3 would have no effect on equilibrium quantities demanded, since the budget line would rotate around the corner of the indifference curve.[nb 2]

Preference relations and utility

Choice theory formally represents consumers by a preference relation, and use this representation to derive indifference curves showing combinations of equal preference to the consumer.

Preference relations

Let

be a set of mutually exclusive alternatives among which a consumer can choose.
and be generic elements of .

In the language of the example above, the set is made of combinations of apples and bananas. The symbol is one such combination, such as 1 apple and 4 bananas and is another combination such as 2 apples and 2 bananas.

A preference relation, denoted , is a binary relation define on the set .

The statement

is described as ' is weakly preferred to .' That is, is at least as good as (in preference satisfaction).

The statement

is described as ' is weakly preferred to , and is weakly preferred to .' That is, one is indifferent to the choice of or , meaning not that they are unwanted but that they are equally good in satisfying preferences.

The statement

is described as ' is weakly preferred to , but is not weakly preferred to .' One says that ' is strictly preferred to .'

The preference relation is complete if all pairs can be ranked. The relation is a transitive relation if whenever and then .

For any element , the corresponding indifference curve, is made up of all elements of which are indifferent to . Formally,

.

In the example above, an element of the set is made of two numbers: The number of apples, call it and the number of bananas, call it

In utility theory, the utility function of an agent is a function that ranks all pairs of consumption bundles by order of preference (completeness) such that any set of three or more bundles forms a transitive relation. This means that for each bundle there is a unique relation, , representing the utility (satisfaction) relation associated with . The relation is called the utility function. The range of the function is a set of real numbers. The actual values of the function have no importance. Only the ranking of those values has content for the theory. More precisely, if , then the bundle is described as at least as good as the bundle . If , the bundle is described as strictly preferred to the bundle .

Consider a particular bundle and take the total derivative of about this point:

or, without loss of generality,

(Eq. 1)

where is the partial derivative of with respect to its first argument, evaluated at . (Likewise for )

The indifference curve through must deliver at each bundle on the curve the same utility level as bundle . That is, when preferences are represented by a utility function, the indifference curves are the level curves of the utility function. Therefore, if one is to change the quantity of by , without moving off the indifference curve, one must also change the quantity of by an amount such that, in the end, there is no change in U:

, or, substituting 0 into (Eq. 1) above to solve for dy/dx:
.

Thus, the ratio of marginal utilities gives the absolute value of the slope of the indifference curve at point . This ratio is called the marginal rate of substitution between and .

Examples

Linear utility

If the utility function is of the form then the marginal utility of is and the marginal utility of is . The slope of the indifference curve is, therefore,

Observe that the slope does not depend on or : the indifference curves are straight lines.

Cobb–Douglas utility

A class of utility functions known as Cobb-Douglas utility functions are very commonly used in economics for two reasons:

1. They represent ‘well-behaved’ preferences, such as more is better and preference for variety.

2. They are very flexible and can be adjusted to fit real-world data very easily. If the utility function is of the form the marginal utility of is and the marginal utility of is .Where . The slope of the indifference curve, and therefore the negative of the marginal rate of substitution, is then

CES utility

A general CES (Constant Elasticity of Substitution) form is

where and . (The Cobb–Douglas is a special case of the CES utility, with .) The marginal utilities are given by

and

Therefore, along an indifference curve,

These examples might be useful for modelling individual or aggregate demand.

Biology

As used in biology, the indifference curve is a model for how animals 'decide' whether to perform a particular behavior, based on changes in two variables which can increase in intensity, one along the x-axis and the other along the y-axis. For example, the x-axis may measure the quantity of food available while the y-axis measures the risk involved in obtaining it. The indifference curve is drawn to predict the animal's behavior at various levels of risk and food availability.

Criticisms

Indifference curves inherit the criticisms directed at utility more generally.

Herbert Hovenkamp (1991)[13] has argued that the presence of an endowment effect has significant implications for law and economics, particularly in regard to welfare economics. He argues that the presence of an endowment effect indicates that a person has no indifference curve (see however Hanemann, 1991[14]) rendering the neoclassical tools of welfare analysis useless, concluding that courts should instead use WTA as a measure of value. Fischel (1995)[15] however, raises the counterpoint that using WTA as a measure of value would deter the development of a nation's infrastructure and economic growth.

Austrian economist Murray Rothbard criticised the indifference curve as "never by definition exhibited in action, in actual exchanges, and is therefore unknowable and objectively meaningless."[16]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ The transitivity of weak preferences is sufficient for most indifference-curve analyses: If A is weakly preferred to B, meaning that the consumer likes A at least as much as B, and B is weakly preferred to C, then A is weakly preferred to C.[8]
  2. ^ Indifference curves can be used to derive the individual demand curve. However, the assumptions of consumer preference theory do not guarantee that the demand curve will have a negative slope.[12]

References

  1. ^ Geanakoplos, John (1987). "Arrow-Debreu model of general equilibrium". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 1. pp. 116–124 [p. 117].
  2. ^ Böhm, Volker; Haller, Hans (1987). "Demand theory". The New Palgrave: A Dictionary of Economics. Vol. 1. pp. 785–792 [p. 785].
  3. ^ Francis Ysidro Edgeworth (1881). Mathematical Psychics: An Essay on the Application of Mathematics to the Moral Sciences. London: C. Kegan Paul and Co.
  4. ^ Vilfredo Pareto (1919). Manuale di Economia Politica — con una Introduzione alla Scienza Sociale [Manual of Political Economy]. Piccola Biblioteca Scientifica. Vol. 13. Milano: Societa Editrice Libraria.
  5. ^ "Indifference curves | Policonomics". Retrieved 2018-12-08.
  6. ^ "William Stanley Jevons - Policonomics". www.policonomics.com. Retrieved 23 March 2018.
  7. ^ a b c d e f g Binger; Hoffman (1998). Microeconomics with Calculus (2nd ed.). Reading: Addison-Wesley. pp. 109–117. ISBN 0-321-01225-9.
  8. ^ a b Perloff, Jeffrey M. (2008). Microeconomics: Theory & Applications with Calculus. Boston: Addison-Wesley. p. 62. ISBN 978-0-321-27794-7.
  9. ^ a b c Silberberg; Suen (2000). The Structure of Economics: A Mathematical Analysis (3rd ed.). Boston: McGraw-Hill. ISBN 0-07-118136-9.
  10. ^ a b Lipsey, Richard G. (1975). An Introduction to Positive Economics (Fourth ed.). Weidenfeld & Nicolson. pp. 182–186. ISBN 0-297-76899-9.
  11. ^ Salvatore, Dominick (1989). Schaum's Outline of Theory and Problems of Managerial Economics. McGraw-Hill. ISBN 0-07-054513-8.
  12. ^ Binger; Hoffman (1998). Microeconomics with Calculus (2nd ed.). Reading: Addison-Wesley. pp. 141–143. ISBN 0-321-01225-9.
  13. ^ Hovenkamp, Herbert (1991). "Legal Policy and the Endowment Effect". The Journal of Legal Studies. 20 (2): 225. doi:10.1086/467886. S2CID 155051169.
  14. ^ Hanemann, W. Michael (1991). "Willingness To Pay and Willingness To Accept: How Much Can They Differ? Reply". American Economic Review. 81 (3): 635–647. doi:10.1257/000282803321455449. JSTOR 2006525.
  15. ^ Fischel, William A. (1995). "The offer/ask disparity and just compensation for takings: A constitutional choice perspective". International Review of Law and Economics. 15 (2): 187–203. doi:10.1016/0144-8188(94)00005-F.
  16. ^ Rothbard, Murray (1998). The Ethics of Liberty. New York University Press. p. 242. ISBN 9780814775592.

Further reading

Read other articles:

テレビ番組・中継内での各種情報(終了した番組・中継を含みます)は、DVDやBlu-rayなどでの販売や公式なネット配信、または信頼できる紙媒体またはウェブ媒体が紹介するまで、出典として用いないで下さい。検証可能性に基づき除去される場合があります。 この記事は検証可能な参考文献や出典が全く示されていないか、不十分です。出典を追加して記事の信頼性向...

 

Kesetimbangan kelarutan adalah sejenis kesetimbangan dinamis yang ada bila senyawa kimia dalam keadaan padat berada dalam kesetimbangan kimia dengan larutannya. Padatan dapat larut tanpa perubahan, disertai disosiasi, atau disertai reaksi kimia dengan konstituen lain, seperti asam atau basa. Setiap jenis kesetimbangan dicirikan oleh konstanta kesetimbangan yang bergantung pada suhu. Kesetimbangan kelarutan penting dalam skenario farmasi, lingkungan dan banyak lainnya. Definisi Suatu kesetimba...

 

This article does not cite any sources. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Aghibasiin-Lessons on How to Defeat Death – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (July 2011) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) 2004 compilation album by Naer MataronAghibasiin-Lessons on How To Defeat DeathCompilation album by Naer MataronReleas...

Thelma Payne Thelma Payne, später Thelma Sanborn, (* 18. Juli 1896 in Salem, Oregon; † 7. September 1988 in Laguna Niguel, Kalifornien) war eine Wasserspringerin aus den Vereinigten Staaten. Sie gewann eine olympische Bronzemedaille. Karriere Thelma Payne startete für den Multnomah Athletic Club in Portland. Sie war von 1918 bis 1920 dreimal in Folge Hallenmeisterin der Amateur Athletic Union im Kunstspringen. Bei den Olympischen Spielen in Antwerpen traten nur vier Springerinnen aus den ...

 

Former currency of the Kingdom of Westphalia This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Westphalian frank – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (May 2008) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) A gold 10 Franken coin The Westphalian frank was a currency of the Kingdom of Westphalia...

 

يفتقر محتوى هذه المقالة إلى الاستشهاد بمصادر. فضلاً، ساهم في تطوير هذه المقالة من خلال إضافة مصادر موثوق بها. أي معلومات غير موثقة يمكن التشكيك بها وإزالتها. (يناير 2021) غروت بريجس جيف شيرنز 2019 تفاصيل السباقسلسلة53. غروت بريجس جيف شيرنزمنافسةطواف أوروبا للدراجات 2019 1.1‏التار

Santo Georgius di hadapan Diokletianus, penggambaran sebuah mural abad ke-14 di Ubisi. Pemerintahan Kaisar Diokletianus (284−305) merupakan masa penindasan atau penganiayaan terakhir yang berlangsung secara luas terhadap umat Kristiani di Kekaisaran Romawi. Periode kekerasan yang paling intens terjadi setelah Diokletianus mengeluarkan suatu maklumat pada tahun 303 untuk menerapkan ketaatan yang lebih ketat terhadap praktik-praktik keagamaan tradisional di Roma terkait dengan kultus Imperial...

 

هذه المقالة تحتاج للمزيد من الوصلات للمقالات الأخرى للمساعدة في ترابط مقالات الموسوعة. فضلًا ساعد في تحسين هذه المقالة بإضافة وصلات إلى المقالات المتعلقة بها الموجودة في النص الحالي. (نوفمبر 2019) هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة...

 

NARUTO -ナルト- > NARUTO -ナルト- ナルティメットヒーロー > NARUTO X BORUTO ナルティメットストームコネクションズ この項目は、発売前あるいは配信・稼働開始前のコンピュータゲームを扱っています。情報が解禁されていくに従い、この項目の内容も大きく変化することがありますのでご注意ください。投稿者は推測や予想を加えないようにしてください。投稿...

Artikel ini mengenai Allah dalam istilah Kekristenan di Indonesia dan bukan mengenai Allah, Tuhan dalam Islam. Untuk pemahaman lebih lanjut, lihat artikel Penggunaan Allah bagi umat Kristen Indonesia. Gereja Sidang-Sidang Jemaat Allah di IndonesiaLogo GSJAPenggolonganPentakostaPemimpinPdt Budi SetiawanWilayahIndonesiaDidirikan1945 Gereja Sidang Sidang Jemaat Allah, disingkat GSJA, adalah salah satu sinode gereja Kristen Pentakosta di Indonesia yang bernaung di bawah Persekutuan Gereja-gereja ...

 

Clint EastwoodEastwood at the 61st Annual Cannes Film Festival (2008)BornClint Eastwood Jr. (1930-05-31) May 31, 1930 (age 93)San Francisco, California, U.S.OccupationsActorfilm directorproducerYears active1954–present This article is part of a series about Clint Eastwood Early life Personal life Political life 2012 RNC appearance Filmography Discography Bibliography Awards and honors Malpaso Productions Man with No Name Harry Callahan Go ahead, make my day vte Clint Eastwood is a...

 

Moldovan footballer Oleksandr Kucherenko Personal informationFull name Oleksandr Yevhenovych KucherenkoDate of birth (1991-10-01) 1 October 1991 (age 32)Place of birth Sloviansk, UkraineHeight 1.84 m (6 ft 0 in)Position(s) Defensive midfielderTeam informationCurrent team Veres RivneNumber 23Youth career Slovkhlib SlovyanskSenior career*Years Team Apps (Gls)2009–2010 Slovkhlib Slovyansk 2 (0)2011 Avanhard Kramatorsk 14 (1)2011–2013 Nistru Otaci 41 (3)2013–2014 Costule...

Large rainforest in South America For other uses, see Amazon and Amazonia (disambiguation). Amazon rainforestPortuguese: Floresta amazônicaSpanish: Selva amazónicaDutch: AmazoneregenwoudAerial view of the Amazon rainforest near ManausMapMap of the Amazon rainforest ecoregions as delineated by the WWF in dark green[1] and the Amazon drainage basin in light green.GeographyLocationBolivia, Brazil, Colombia, Ecuador, French Guiana (France), Guyana, Peru, Suriname, and VenezuelaCoordinat...

 

This article relies largely or entirely on a single source. Relevant discussion may be found on the talk page. Please help improve this article by introducing citations to additional sources.Find sources: Muhammad Muradyab Khan – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (April 2018) Nawab of Sindh Muhammad Muradyab KhanNawab of SindhReign1755 – 1758PredecessorNoor Mohammad KalhoroSuccessorMian Ghulam Shah KalhoroDiedc. 1758NamesMian Muhammad Murad...

 

Sede de la agencia en Kioto. Edificio de las oficinas en Tokio, en 2005, con decoración kadomatsu. La Agencia para Asuntos Culturales (文化庁, bunkachō?) es un organismo especial del Ministerio de Educación, Cultura, Deportes, Ciencia y Tecnología (MEXT) de Japón. Fue creado en 1968 para promover las artes y la cultura japonesa. Desde el 27 de marzo de 2023, la agencia cuenta con sede principal en Kioto.[1]​ Previamente se encontraba en el barrio de Chiyoda. El Comisionado para ...

Constituent emirate of the United Arab Emirates This article is about the Emirate of Abu Dhabi. For the city of Abu Dhabi, see Abu Dhabi. Emirate in United Arab EmiratesEmirate of Abu Dhabi إِمَـارَة أَبُـوظَـبِيEmirate FlagCoat of armsLocation of Abu Dhabi in the UAECoordinates: 23°30′N 54°30′E / 23.5°N 54.5°E / 23.5; 54.5Country United Arab EmiratesIndependence from the UK2 December 1971SeatAbu DhabiSubdivisions 3 Municipal Regions A...

 

Highway in New York Bronx River ParkwayBronx River Parkway highlighted in redRoute informationMaintained by NYSDOT and Westchester CountyLength19.12 mi[1] (30.77 km)Existed1908–presentHistoryCompleted in 1952TouristroutesNew York State Scenic BywayRestrictionsNo commercial vehiclesMajor junctionsSouth end I-278 / Story Avenue in SoundviewMajor intersections I-95 in West Farms US 1 / Pelham Parkway in Bronx Park Mosholu Parkway / Allerton Avenue in Bronx...

 

Economic sector in Bangladesh Development of agricultural output of Bangladesh in 2019 US$ since 1961 As watercourses such as canals, both natural and manmade, and rivers contribute as the vital source of irrigation, their spread across the country is attributed as a key factor for the economic and geographic extent of agriculture in Bangladesh. Photographed is a process of irrigation underway in Comilla, enabled by a pump that is extracting water from the Gumti seen in the background. Agricu...

Feeling of difficulty breathing Medical conditionShortness of breathOther namesDyspnea, dyspnoea, breathlessness, difficulty (in/of) breathing; respiratory distressPronunciationDyspnea: /dɪspˈniːə/; see also § Etymology and pronunciation SpecialtyPulmonology Shortness of breath (SOB), also medically known as dyspnea (in AmE) or dyspnoea (in BrE), is an uncomfortable feeling of not being able to breathe well enough. The American Thoracic Society defines it as a subjective experi...

 

Coat of arms of the City of London. The Town Clerk of London is an important position that has existed since the 13th century in the City of London, England. Originally the role was to take the minutes of London council meetings, but over the years the holder's role has gathered responsibility, including staff and executive powers. Historically the incumbent received an annual fee of £10.[1] This has risen to £244,000 in 2016/17, with 55% coming from the City Fund[2] and 40%...

 

Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!