The Schulze method (/ˈʃʊltsə/), also known as the beatpath method, is a single winnerranked-choice voting rule developed by Markus Schulze. The Schulze method is a Condorcet completion method, which means it will elect a majority-preferred candidate if one exists. In other words, if most people rank A above B, A will defeat B (whenever this is possible). Schulze's method breaks cyclic ties by using indirect victories. The idea is that if Alice beats Bob, and Bob beats Charlie, then Alice (indirectly) beats Charlie; this kind of indirect win is called a "beatpath".
Schulze's method uses ranked ballots with equal ratings allowed. There are two common (equivalent) descriptions of Schulze's method.
Beatpath explanation
The idea behind Schulze's method is that if Alice defeats Bob, and Bob beats Charlie, then Alice "indirectly" defeats Charlie. These chained sequences of "beats" are called 'beatpaths'.
Every beatpath is assigned a particular strength. The strength of a single-step beatpath from Alice to Bob is just the number of voters who rank Alice over Bob. For a longer beatpath, consisting of multiple beats, a beatpath is as strong as its weakest link (i.e. the beat with the smallest number of winning votes).
We say Alice has a "beatpath-win" over Bob if her strongest beatpath to Bob is stronger than all of Bob's strongest beatpaths to Alice. The winner is the candidate who has a beatpath-win over every other candidate.
Markus Schulze proved that this definition of a beatpath-win is transitive: in other words, if Alice has a beatpath-win over Bob, and Bob has a beatpath-win over Charlie, Alice has a beatpath-win over Charlie.[1]: §4.1 As a result, the Schulze method is a Condorcet method, providing a full extension of the majority rule to any set of ballots.
Iterative description
The Schulze winner can also be constructed iteratively, using a defeat-dropping method:
Draw a directed graph with all the candidates as nodes; label the edges with the number of votes supporting the winner.
If there is more than one candidate left:
Check if any candidates are tied (and if so, break the ties by random ballot).
The winner is the only candidate left at the end of the procedure.
Example
In the following example 45 voters rank 5 candidates.
Number of voters
Order of preference
5
ACBED
5
ADECB
8
BEDAC
3
CABED
7
CAEBD
2
CBADE
7
DCEBA
8
EBADC
The pairwise preferences have to be computed first. For example, when comparing A and B pairwise, there are 5+5+3+7=20 voters who prefer A to B, and 8+2+7+8=25 voters who prefer B to A. So and . The full set of pairwise preferences is:
Matrix of pairwise preferences
20
26
30
22
25
16
33
18
19
29
17
24
15
12
28
14
23
27
21
31
The cells for d[X, Y] have a light green background if d[X, Y] > d[Y, X], otherwise the background is light red. There is no undisputed winner by only looking at the pairwise differences here.
Now the strongest paths have to be identified. To help visualize the strongest paths, the set of pairwise preferences is depicted in the diagram on the right in the form of a directed graph. An arrow from the node representing a candidate X to the one representing a candidate Y is labelled with d[X, Y]. To avoid cluttering the diagram, an arrow has only been drawn from X to Y when d[X, Y] > d[Y, X] (i.e. the table cells with light green background), omitting the one in the opposite direction (the table cells with light red background).
One example of computing the strongest path strength is p[B, D] = 33: the strongest path from B to D is the direct path (B, D) which has strength 33. But when computing p[A, C], the strongest path from A to C is not the direct path (A, C) of strength 26, rather the strongest path is the indirect path (A, D, C) which has strength min(30, 28) = 28. The strength of a path is the strength of its weakest link.
For each pair of candidates X and Y, the following table shows the strongest path from candidate X to candidate Y in red, with the weakest link underlined.
Strongest paths
To
From
A
B
C
D
E
A
—
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
A-(30)-D-(28)-C
A-(30)-D
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E
A
B
B-(25)-A
—
B-(33)-D-(28)-C
B-(33)-D
B-(33)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E
B
C
C-(29)-B-(25)-A
C-(29)-B
—
C-(29)-B-(33)-D
C-(24)-E
C
D
D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
D-(28)-C-(29)-B
D-(28)-C
—
D-(28)-C-(24)-E
D
E
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
E-(31)-D-(28)-C
E-(31)-D
—
E
A
B
C
D
E
From
To
Strengths of the strongest paths
28
28
30
24
25
28
33
24
25
29
29
24
25
28
28
24
25
28
28
31
Now the output of the Schulze method can be determined. For example, when comparing A and B, since , for the Schulze method candidate A is better than candidate B. Another example is that , so candidate E is better than candidate D. Continuing in this way, the result is that the Schulze ranking is , and E wins. In other words, E wins since for every other candidate X.
Implementation
The only difficult step in implementing the Schulze method is computing the strongest path strengths. However, this is a well-known problem in graph theory sometimes called the widest path problem. One simple way to compute the strengths, therefore, is a variant of the Floyd–Warshall algorithm. The following pseudocode illustrates the algorithm.
# Input: d[i,j], the number of voters who prefer candidate i to candidate j.
# Output: p[i,j], the strength of the strongest path from candidate i to candidate j.
for i from 1 to C
for j from 1 to C
if i ≠ j then
if d[i,j] > d[j,i] then
p[i,j] := d[i,j]
else
p[i,j] := 0
for i from 1 to C
for j from 1 to C
if i ≠ j then
for k from 1 to C
if i ≠ k and j ≠ k then
p[j,k] := max (p[j,k], min (p[j,i], p[i,k]))
When allowing users to have ties in their preferences, the outcome of the Schulze method naturally depends on how these ties are interpreted in defining d[*,*]. Two natural choices are that d[A, B] represents either the number of voters who strictly prefer A to B (A>B), or the margin of (voters with A>B) minus (voters with B>A). But no matter how the ds are defined, the Schulze ranking has no cycles, and assuming the ds are unique it has no ties.[2]
Although ties in the Schulze ranking are unlikely, they are possible. Schulze's original paper recommended breaking ties by random ballot.[2]
There is another alternative way to demonstrate the winner of the Schulze method. This method is equivalent to the others described here, but the presentation is optimized for the significance of steps being visually apparent as a human goes through it, not for computation.
Make the results table, called the "matrix of pairwise preferences", such as used above in the example. Then, every positive number is a pairwise win for the candidate on that row (and marked green), ties are zeroes, and losses are negative (marked red). Order the candidates by how long they last in elimination.
If there is a candidate with no red on their line, they win.
Otherwise, draw a square box around the Schwartz set in the upper left corner. It can be described as the minimal "winner's circle" of candidates who do not lose to anyone outside the circle. Note that to the right of the box there is no red, which means it is a winner's circle, and note that within the box there is no reordering possible that would produce a smaller winner's circle.
Cut away every part of the table outside the box.
If there is still no candidate with no red on their line, something needs to be compromised on; every candidate lost some race, and the loss we tolerate the best is the one where the loser obtained the most votes. So, take the red cell with the highest number (if going by margins, the least negative), make it green—or any color other than red—and go back step 2.
Here is a margins table made from the above example. Note the change of order used for demonstration purposes.
Initial results table
E
A
C
B
D
E
1
−3
9
17
A
−1
7
−5
15
C
3
−7
13
−11
B
−9
5
−13
21
D
−17
−15
11
−21
The first drop (A's loss to E by 1 vote) does not help shrink the Schwartz set.
First drop
E
A
C
B
D
E
1
−3
9
17
A
−1
7
−5
15
C
3
−7
13
−11
B
−9
5
−13
21
D
−17
−15
11
−21
So we get straight to the second drop (E's loss to C by 3 votes), and that shows us the winner, E, with its clear row.
Second drop, final
E
A
C
B
D
E
1
−3
9
17
A
−1
7
−5
15
C
3
−7
13
−11
B
−9
5
−13
21
D
−17
−15
11
−21
This method can also be used to calculate a result, if the table is remade in such a way that one can conveniently and reliably rearrange the order of the candidates on both the row and the column, with the same order used on both at all times.
Satisfied and failed criteria
Satisfied criteria
The Schulze method satisfies the following criteria:
^ abA variant of Minimax that counts only pairwise opposition, not opposition minus support, fails the Condorcet criterion and meets later-no-harm.
^ abcIn Highest median, Ranked Pairs, and Schulze voting, there is always a regret-free, semi-honest ballot for any voter, holding all other ballots constant and assuming they know enough about how others will vote. Under such circumstances, there is always at least one way for a voter to participate without grading any less-preferred candidate above any more-preferred one.
^ abcApproval voting, score voting, and majority judgment satisfy IIA if it is assumed that voters rate candidates independently using their own absolute scale. For this to hold, in some elections, some voters must use less than their full voting power despite having meaningful preferences among viable candidates.
^Majority Judgment may elect a candidate uniquely least-preferred by over half of voters, but it never elects the candidate uniquely bottom-rated by over half of voters.
^Majority Judgment fails the mutual majority criterion, but satisfies the criterion if the majority ranks the mutually favored set above a given absolute grade and all others below that grade.
^A randomly chosen ballot determines winner. This and closely related methods are of mathematical interest and included here to demonstrate that even unreasonable methods can pass voting method criteria.
^Where a winner is randomly chosen from the candidates, sortition is included to demonstrate that even non-voting methods can pass some criteria.
Difference from ranked pairs
Ranked pairs is another Condorcet method which is very similar to Schulze's rule, and typically produces the same outcome. There are slight differences, however. The main difference between the beatpath method and ranked pairs is that Schulze retains behavior closer to minimax. Say that the minimax score of a set X of candidates is the strength of the strongest pairwise win of a candidate A ∉ X against a candidate B ∈ X. Then the Schulze method, but not ranked pairs, guarantees the winner is always a candidate of the set with minimum minimax score.[2]: §4.8 This is the sense in which the Schulze method minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed when determining the winner.
On the other hand, Ranked Pairs minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed to determine the order of finish.[5] In other words, when Ranked Pairs and the Schulze method produce different orders of finish, for the majorities on which the two orders of finish disagree, the Schulze order reverses a larger majority than the Ranked Pairs order.
History
The Schulze method was developed by Markus Schulze in 1997. It was first discussed in public mailing lists in 1997–1998[6] and in 2000.[7] In 2011, Schulze published the method in the academic journal Social Choice and Welfare.[2]
^Hortanoticias, Redacción (2016-02-23). "Al voltant de 2.000 participants en dos dies en la primera enquesta popular de Silla que decidirà sobre espectacles taurins". Hortanoticias.com (in Spanish). Retrieved 2022-09-24. S'utilitzarà el sistema de recompte Schulze perquè és un sistema de vot preferencial que compleix amb el criteri de Condorcet, la qual cosa permet identificar l'opció que, comparada amb qualsevol de les altres, és preferida per la majoria absoluta dels votants [The Schulze counting system will be used because it is a preferential voting system that complies with the Condorcet criterion, which makes it possible to identify the option that, compared to any other option, is preferred by the absolute majority of voters]
^"22-26 de febrer: La primera Enquesta Popular de la història de Silla - Notícies - Ajuntament de Silla". Silla Town Council (in Catalan). 2016-02-23. Archived from the original on 2016-02-23. Retrieved 2024-12-13. S'utilitzarà el sistema de recompte Schulze perquè és un sistema de vot preferencial que compleix amb el criteri de Condorcet, la qual cosa permet identificar l'opció que, comparada amb qualsevol de les altres, és preferida per la majoria absoluta dels votants. [The Schulze counting system will be used because it is a preferential voting system that complies with the Condorcet criterion, which makes it possible to identify the option that, compared to any of the others, is preferred by the absolute majority of voters.]
^"UN AÑO DE PROFUNDIZACIÓN DEMOCRÁTICA EN SILLA | Silla en Democracia". Silla in Democracy (in Spanish). 2017-03-22. Archived from the original on 2017-03-22. Retrieved 2024-12-13. Ha sido un rotundo éxito organizativo que repetiremos y que se gestó desde meses antes, desarrollando un know-how propio y siendo pioneros en la aplicación del sistema de recuento Condorcet-Schulze para las preguntas con respuesta de ordenación preferencial. Logramos un récord impresionante de participación que pulverizó todas las marcas existentes en procesos similares en municipios españoles (la media usual ronda el 10% de participación mientras que en Silla alcanzamos el 27%). [It has been a resounding organizational success that we will repeat, developed over months with our own know-how, and pioneering the application of the Condorcet-Schulze counting system for questions with preferential ranking responses. We achieved an impressive participation record that shattered all existing benchmarks in similar processes in Spanish municipalities (the usual average is around 10% participation, while in Silla, we reached 27%).]
^"Algorithms for Good (The Liquid Democracy Journal, Issue 7)". liquid-democracy-journal.org. Retrieved 2024-12-13. To determine the winner from a set of alternatives, LiquidFeedback implements Clone-Proof Schwartz Sequential Dropping, known as the Schulze Method.
Staff carried by Hermes in Greek mythology This article is about the Greek symbol. For the (mis)usage as a medical symbol, see Caduceus as a symbol of medicine. For the medical symbol with one snake, often mistakenly referred to as a caduceus, see Rod of Asclepius. For other uses, see Caduceus (disambiguation). Modern depiction of the caduceus as the symbol of logistics Hermes Ingenui[a] carrying a winged caduceus upright in his left hand. A Roman copy after a Greek original of the 5t...
اضغط هنا للاطلاع على كيفية قراءة التصنيف سيفاكا كوكريلي حالة الحفظ أنواع مهددة بالانقراض (خطر انقراض أقصى)[1] المرتبة التصنيفية نوع[2] التصنيف العلمي النطاق: حقيقيات النوى المملكة: حيوانات الفرقة العليا: البعديات الحقيقية القسم: ثانويات الفم الشعبة: الحبليات الشع
Leiberstung Gemeinde Sinzheim Wappen von Leiberstung vor der Eingemeindung Koordinaten: 48° 45′ N, 8° 6′ O48.75358.09957123Koordinaten: 48° 45′ 13″ N, 8° 5′ 58″ O Höhe: 123 m ü. NHN Einwohner: 865 (31. Dez. 2020)[1] Eingemeindung: 1. Januar 1973 Postleitzahl: 76547 Vorwahl: 07223 Leiberstung ist seit der Kommunalreform in Baden-Württemberg 1973 ein Ortsteil der Gemeinde Sinzheim im südl...
Fernando Andrés Rapallini[1] (* 28. April 1978 in La Plata, Buenos Aires)[2] ist ein argentinischer Fußballschiedsrichter. Seit 2014 steht er auf der FIFA-Liste.[3] Inhaltsverzeichnis 1 Werdegang 1.1 Einsätze bei der Fußball-Europameisterschaft 2021 1.2 Einsätze bei der Fußball-Weltmeisterschaft 2022 2 Persönliches 3 Einzelnachweise Werdegang Rapallini begann seine Schiedsrichterkarriere 2001.[4] Seit 2011 leitet Rapallini Spiele der Primera División, d...
Untuk kegunaan lain, lihat Nusakambangan (disambiguasi). NusakambanganGeografiLokasiAsia TenggaraKoordinat7°45′S 108°55′E / 7.750°S 108.917°E / -7.750; 108.917Luas121 km2PemerintahanNegara IndonesiaProvinsiJawa TengahKabupatenCilacapKependudukanPenduduk~3.000 jiwa Nusakambangan adalah sebuah pulau di Jawa Tengah yang lebih dikenal sebagai tempat terletaknya beberapa Lembaga Pemasyarakatan (Lapas) berkeamanan tinggi di Indonesia. Secara Geografis,...
Paolo Martinelli Bispo da Igreja Católica Vigário apostólico da Arábia Meridional Hierarquia Papa Francisco Ordem Religiosa Roberto Genuin, O.F.M.Cap. Atividade eclesiástica Ordem Ordem dos Frades Menores Capuchinhos Diocese Vicariato Apostólico da Arábia Meridional Nomeação 1 de maio de 2022 Predecessor Paul Hinder, O.F.M.Cap. Mandato 2022 - Ordenação e nomeação Ordenação presbiteral 7 de setembro de 1985por Renato Corti Nomeação episcopal 24 de maio de 2014 Ordenação epis...
Bài viết này là một phần của loạt bài vềChính trị Trung QuốcCộng hòa Nhân dân Trung Hoa Lãnh đạo Trung Quốc Thế hệ Lãnh đạo Hiến pháp Trung Quốc Lãnh đạo Tối cao Mao Trạch Đông (1949–1976) Hoa Quốc Phong (1976–1978) Đặng Tiểu Bình (1978–1997) Giang Trạch Dân (1997–2002) Hồ Cẩm Đào (2002–2012) Tập Cận Bình (từ 2012) Tổng Bí thư: Tập Cận Bình Chủ tịch nước: Tập Cận B...
US pulp magazine The All-Story (June 1912), containing part five of six of Edgar Rice Burroughs' Under the Moons of Mars The All-Story Magazine was a Munsey pulp. Debuting in January 1905 (the word Magazine was dropped from the title in 1908), this pulp was published monthly until March 1914. Effective March 7, 1914, it changed to a weekly schedule and the title All-Story Weekly. In May 1914, All-Story Weekly was merged with another story pulp, The Cavalier, and used the title All-Story Caval...
рос. 43-й отдельный морской штурмовой авиационный полк Країна СРСР → РосіяВид Повітряно-космічні силиТип окремий морський десантно-штурмовий авіаційний полкУ складі Чорноморський флот РФАвіабаза СакиКомандуванняПоточнийкомандувач рос. Киселев Андрей Леонид...
Art exhibition periodically held in Paris from 1667 to the late 19th century Formally dressed patrons at the Salon in 1890. 'Un Jour de vernissage au palais des Champs-Élysées by Jean-André Rixens featuring Tigresse apportant un paon à ses petits by Auguste Cain. The Salon (French: Salon), or rarely Paris Salon (French: Salon de Paris [salɔ̃ də paʁi]), beginning in 1667[1] was the official art exhibition of the Académie des Beaux-Arts in Paris. Between 1748 and 1890 i...
Artikel ini memberikan informasi dasar tentang topik kesehatan. Informasi dalam artikel ini hanya boleh digunakan hanya untuk penjelasan ilmiah, bukan untuk diagnosis diri dan tidak dapat menggantikan diagnosis medis. Perhatian: Informasi dalam artikel ini bukanlah resep atau nasihat medis. Wikipedia tidak memberikan konsultasi medis. Jika Anda perlu bantuan atau hendak berobat, berkonsultasilah dengan tenaga kesehatan profesional. BronkitisGambar A menunjukkan letak dari paru-paru dan bronku...
Theatre and cinema in Milford Haven, Pembrokeshire, Wales Torch TheatreAddressSt. Peter's RoadMilford Haven, WalesOwnerTorch Theatre CompanyCapacity297 (Main House)102 (Studio Theatre)Opened1977Websitewww.torchtheatre.co.uk The Torch Theatre is a not-for-profit theatre in Milford Haven, Wales. Established in 1977, it is one of only three building-based producing theatres in the whole of Wales. The initial concept was a small community enterprise, linked with a Further Education centre in the ...
Human settlement in EnglandLow MarnhamSt Wilfrid's ChurchLow MarnhamLocation within NottinghamshireOS grid referenceSK8069Civil parishMarnhamDistrictBassetlawShire countyNottinghamshireRegionEast MidlandsCountryEnglandSovereign stateUnited KingdomPost townNewark-on-TrentPostcode districtNG23PoliceNottinghamshireFireNottinghamshireAmbulanceEast Midlands UK ParliamentNewark List of places UK England Nottinghamshire 53°12′56″N 0°47′36″W / 5...
The Kafka Effekt AuthorD. Harlan WilsonCover artistBrandon DuncanCountryUnited StatesLanguageEnglishGenreIrrealism, Bizarro fiction, PostmodernismPublisherEraserhead PressPublication dateNovember 2001Media typePrintPages211 ppISBN0-9713572-1-8OCLC49633671Followed byStranger on the Loose The Kafka Effekt (2001) is the debut book of American author D. Harlan Wilson.[1] It contains forty-four irreal short stories and flash fiction and has been said to combine the mil...
Shopping mall in Ardmore, PennsylvaniaSuburban SquareSuburban Square, 2019LocationArdmore, PennsylvaniaCoordinates40°00′30″N 75°17′17″W / 40.00833°N 75.28806°W / 40.00833; -75.28806Opening date1928ManagementKimco RealtyOwnerKimco RealtyNo. of stores and services60+Total retail floor area355,000 square feet (33,000 m2)[1]ParkingParking lotWebsitesuburbansquare.com Suburban Square is a community shopping center in Ardmore, Pennsylvania, United St...
Theatrical and technical live entertainment production division of the Walt Disney Company This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Disney Live Entertainment – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (July 2022) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Disney Live EntertainmentFormerly...
Fictional moon in Star Wars The topic of this article may not meet Wikipedia's general notability guideline. Please help to demonstrate the notability of the topic by citing reliable secondary sources that are independent of the topic and provide significant coverage of it beyond a mere trivial mention. If notability cannot be shown, the article is likely to be merged, redirected, or deleted.Find sources: Endor Star Wars – news · newspapers · books · sc...
1968 book predicting worldwide famine The Population Bomb AuthorsPaul R. Ehrlich, Anne Howland EhrlichCountryUnited StatesLanguageEnglishSubjectPopulationPublisherSierra Club/Ballantine BooksPublication date1968Pages201ISBN1-56849-587-0 The Population Bomb is a 1968 book co-authored by former Stanford University professor Paul R. Ehrlich and former Stanford senior researcher in conservation biology Anne H. Ehrlich.[1][2] From the opening page, it incorrectly predicted worldwid...
Railway station in Jōetsu, Niigata Prefecture, Japan Naoetsu Station直江津駅Naoetsu Station in March 2010General informationLocation1-1 Azuma-cho, Jōetsu-shi, Niigata-ken 942-0003JapanCoordinates37°10′16″N 138°14′35″E / 37.171021°N 138.243113°E / 37.171021; 138.243113Operated by JR East Echigo Tokimeki Railway Line(s) ■ Shinetsu Main Line ■ Myōkō Haneuma Line ■ Nihonkai Hisui Line ■ Hokuhoku Line Platforms3 island platformsOther informationS...
Brandon Bass Bass in riscaldamento con l'uniforme dei Dallas Mavericks Nazionalità Stati Uniti Altezza 203 cm Peso 113 kg Pallacanestro Ruolo Ala grande Termine carriera 2020 Carriera Giovanili Capitol High School2003-2005 LSU Tigers Squadre di club 2005-2007 N.O. Hornets50 (110)2006→ Tulsa 66ers12007-2009 Dallas Mavericks160 (1.340)2009-2011 Orlando Magic126 (1.144)2011-2015 Boston Celtics304 (3.216)2015-2016 L.A. Lakers66 (473)2016-2017 L.A....