Share to: share facebook share twitter share wa share telegram print page

Schulze method

The Schulze method (/ˈʃʊltsə/) is a single winner ranked-choice voting rule developed by Markus Schulze. It is also known as the beatpath method. The Schulze method is a Condorcet method, which means it will elect a majority-choice candidate if one exists; in other words, if most people rank A above B, A will defeat B (whenever this is possible).

Schulze's method is based on the idea of breaking cyclic ties by using indirect victories. The idea is that if Alice beats Bob, and Bob beats Charlie, then Alice (indirectly) beats Charlie; this kind of indirect win is called a beatpath.

For proportional representation, a single transferable vote (STV) variant known as Schulze STV also exists. The Schulze method is used by several organizations including Debian, Ubuntu, Gentoo, Pirate Party political parties and many others. It was also used by Wikimedia prior to their adoption of score voting.

Description of the method

A sample ballot asking voters to order candidates by preference

Schulze's method uses ranked ballots with equal ratings allowed. There are two common (equivalent) descriptions of Schulze's method.

Beatpath explanation

The idea behind Schulze's method is that if Alice defeats Bob, and Bob beats Charlie, then Alice "indirectly" defeats Charlie; this kind of indirect win is called a 'beatpath'.

Every beatpath is assigned a particular strength. The strength of a single-step beatpath from Alice to Bob is just the number of voters who rank Alice over Bob. For a longer beatpath, consisting of multiple "beats", the strength of a beatpath is as strong as its weakest link (i.e. the beat with the smallest number of winning votes).

We say Alice has a "beatpath-win" over Bob if her strongest beatpath to Bob is stronger than all of Bob's beatpaths to Alice. The winner is the candidate who has a beatpath-win over every other candidate.

Markus Schulze proved that this definition of a beatpath-win is transitive; in other words, if Alice has a beatpath-win over Bob, and Bob has a beatpath-win over Charlie, Alice has a beatpath-win over Charlie.[1]: §4.1  As a result, the Schulze method is a Condorcet method, providing a full extension of the majority rule to any set of ballots.

Iterative description

The Schulze winner can also be constructed iteratively, using a defeat-dropping method:

  1. Draw a directed graph with all the candidates as nodes; label the edges with the number of votes supporting the winner.
  2. If there is more than one candidate left:
    • Check if any candidates are tied (and if so, break the ties by random ballot).
    • Eliminate all candidates outside the majority-preferred set.
    • Delete the edge closest to being tied.

The winner is the only candidate left at the end of the procedure.

Example

In the following example 45 voters rank 5 candidates.

Number of voters Order of preference
5 ACBED
5 ADECB
8 BEDAC
3 CABED
7 CAEBD
2 CBADE
7 DCEBA
8 EBADC

The pairwise preferences have to be computed first. For example, when comparing A and B pairwise, there are 5+5+3+7=20 voters who prefer A to B, and 8+2+7+8=25 voters who prefer B to A. So and . The full set of pairwise preferences is:

Directed graph labeled with pairwise preferences d[*, *]
Matrix of pairwise preferences
20 26 30 22
25 16 33 18
19 29 17 24
15 12 28 14
23 27 21 31

The cells for d[X, Y] have a light green background if d[X, Y] > d[Y, X], otherwise the background is light red. There is no undisputed winner by only looking at the pairwise differences here.

Now the strongest paths have to be identified. To help visualize the strongest paths, the set of pairwise preferences is depicted in the diagram on the right in the form of a directed graph. An arrow from the node representing a candidate X to the one representing a candidate Y is labelled with d[X, Y]. To avoid cluttering the diagram, an arrow has only been drawn from X to Y when d[X, Y] > d[Y, X] (i.e. the table cells with light green background), omitting the one in the opposite direction (the table cells with light red background).

One example of computing the strongest path strength is p[B, D] = 33: the strongest path from B to D is the direct path (B, D) which has strength 33. But when computing p[A, C], the strongest path from A to C is not the direct path (A, C) of strength 26, rather the strongest path is the indirect path (A, D, C) which has strength min(30, 28) = 28. The strength of a path is the strength of its weakest link.

For each pair of candidates X and Y, the following table shows the strongest path from candidate X to candidate Y in red, with the weakest link underlined.

Strongest paths
To
From
A B C D E
A
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
A-(30)-D-(28)-C
A-(30)-D
A-(30)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E
A
B
B-(25)-A
B-(33)-D-(28)-C
B-(33)-D
B-(33)-D-(28)-C-(24)-E
B
C
C-(29)-B-(25)-A
C-(29)-B
C-(29)-B-(33)-D
C-(24)-E
C
D
D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
D-(28)-C-(29)-B
D-(28)-C
D-(28)-C-(24)-E
D
E
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B-(25)-A
E-(31)-D-(28)-C-(29)-B
E-(31)-D-(28)-C
E-(31)-D
E
A B C D E
From
To
Strengths of the strongest paths
28 28 30 24
25 28 33 24
25 29 29 24
25 28 28 24
25 28 28 31

Now the output of the Schulze method can be determined. For example, when comparing A and B, since , for the Schulze method candidate A is better than candidate B. Another example is that , so candidate E is better than candidate D. Continuing in this way, the result is that the Schulze ranking is , and E wins. In other words, E wins since for every other candidate X.

Implementation

The only difficult step in implementing the Schulze method is computing the strongest path strengths. However, this is a well-known problem in graph theory sometimes called the widest path problem. One simple way to compute the strengths, therefore, is a variant of the Floyd–Warshall algorithm. The following pseudocode illustrates the algorithm.

# Input: d[i,j], the number of voters who prefer candidate i to candidate j.
# Output: p[i,j], the strength of the strongest path from candidate i to candidate j.

for i from 1 to C
    for j from 1 to C
        if i ≠ j then
            if d[i,j] > d[j,i] then
                p[i,j] := d[i,j]
            else
                p[i,j] := 0

for i from 1 to C
    for j from 1 to C
        if i ≠ j then
            for k from 1 to C
                if i ≠ k and j ≠ k then
                    p[j,k] := max (p[j,k], min (p[j,i], p[i,k]))

This algorithm is efficient and has running time O(C3) where C is the number of candidates.

Ties and alternative implementations

When allowing users to have ties in their preferences, the outcome of the Schulze method naturally depends on how these ties are interpreted in defining d[*,*]. Two natural choices are that d[A, B] represents either the number of voters who strictly prefer A to B (A>B), or the margin of (voters with A>B) minus (voters with B>A). But no matter how the ds are defined, the Schulze ranking has no cycles, and assuming the ds are unique it has no ties.[2]

Although ties in the Schulze ranking are unlikely, they are possible. Schulze's original paper recommended breaking ties by random ballot.[2]

There is another alternative way to demonstrate the winner of the Schulze method. This method is equivalent to the others described here, but the presentation is optimized for the significance of steps being visually apparent as a human goes through it, not for computation.

  1. Make the results table, called the "matrix of pairwise preferences", such as used above in the example. Then, every positive number is a pairwise win for the candidate on that row (and marked green), ties are zeroes, and losses are negative (marked red). Order the candidates by how long they last in elimination.
  2. If there is a candidate with no red on their line, they win.
  3. Otherwise, draw a square box around the Schwartz set in the upper left corner. It can be described as the minimal "winner's circle" of candidates who do not lose to anyone outside the circle. Note that to the right of the box there is no red, which means it is a winner's circle, and note that within the box there is no reordering possible that would produce a smaller winner's circle.
  4. Cut away every part of the table outside the box.
  5. If there is still no candidate with no red on their line, something needs to be compromised on; every candidate lost some race, and the loss we tolerate the best is the one where the loser obtained the most votes. So, take the red cell with the highest number (if going by margins, the least negative), make it green—or any color other than red—and go back step 2.

Here is a margins table made from the above example. Note the change of order used for demonstration purposes.

Initial results table
E A C B D
E 1 −3 9 17
A −1 7 −5 15
C 3 −7 13 −11
B −9 5 −13 21
D −17 −15 11 −21

The first drop (A's loss to E by 1 vote) does not help shrink the Schwartz set.

First drop
E A C B D
E 1 −3 9 17
A −1 7 −5 15
C 3 −7 13 −11
B −9 5 −13 21
D −17 −15 11 −21

So we get straight to the second drop (E's loss to C by 3 votes), and that shows us the winner, E, with its clear row.

Second drop, final
E A C B D
E 1 −3 9 17
A −1 7 −5 15
C 3 −7 13 −11
B −9 5 −13 21
D −17 −15 11 −21

This method can also be used to calculate a result, if the table is remade in such a way that one can conveniently and reliably rearrange the order of the candidates on both the row and the column, with the same order used on both at all times.

Satisfied and failed criteria

Satisfied criteria

The Schulze method satisfies the following criteria:

Failed criteria

Since the Schulze method satisfies the Condorcet criterion, it automatically fails the following criteria:

Likewise, since the Schulze method is not a dictatorship and is a ranked voting system (not rated), Arrow's Theorem implies it fails:

The Schulze method also fails

Comparison table

The following table compares the Schulze method with other single-winner election methods:

Comparison of single-winner voting systems
Criterion


Method
Majority Majority loser Mutual majority Condorcet winner[Tn 1] Condorcet loser Smith[Tn 1] Smith-IIA[Tn 1] IIA/LIIA[Tn 1] Clone­proof Mono­tone Participation Later-no-harm[Tn 1] Later-no-help[Tn 1] No favorite betrayal[Tn 1] Ballot
type
Anti-plurality No Yes No No No No No No No Yes Yes No No Yes Single mark
Approval Yes No No No No No No Yes[Tn 2] Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Appr­ovals
Baldwin Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Black Yes Yes No Yes Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Borda No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes Yes No Yes No Ran­king
Bucklin Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No Yes No No Yes No Ran­king
Coombs Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Ran­king
Copeland Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Dodgson Yes No No Yes No No No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Highest median Yes Yes[Tn 3] No[Tn 4] No No No No Yes[Tn 2] Yes Yes No[Tn 5] No Yes Yes Scores
Instant-runoff Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No Yes No No Yes Yes No Ran­king
Kemeny–Young Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only No Yes No No No No Ran­king
Minimax Yes No No Yes[Tn 6] No No No No No Yes No No[Tn 6] No No Ran­king
Nanson Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No No No No No No No No Ran­king
Plurality Yes No No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes No Single mark
Random ballot[Tn 7] No No No No No No No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Single mark
Ranked pairs Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes LIIA Only Yes Yes No[Tn 5] No No No Ran­king
Runoff Yes Yes No No Yes No No No No No No Yes Yes No Single mark
Schulze Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes No[Tn 5] No No No Ran­king
Score No No No No No No No Yes[Tn 2] Yes Yes Yes No Yes Yes Scores
Sortition[Tn 8] No No No No No No No Yes No Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes None
STAR No Yes No No Yes No No No No Yes No No No No Scores
Tideman alternative Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes No Yes No No No No No Ran­king
Table Notes
  1. ^ a b c d e f g Condorcet's criterion is incompatible with the consistency, participation, later-no-harm, later-no-help, and sincere favorite criteria.
  2. ^ a b c Approval voting, score voting, and majority judgment satisfy IIA if it is assumed that voters rate candidates independently using their own absolute scale. For this to hold, in some elections, some voters must use less than their full voting power despite having meaningful preferences among viable candidates.
  3. ^ Majority Judgment may elect a candidate uniquely least-preferred by over half of voters, but it never elects the candidate uniquely bottom-rated by over half of voters.
  4. ^ Majority Judgment fails the mutual majority criterion, but satisfies the criterion if the majority ranks the mutually favored set above a given absolute grade and all others below that grade.
  5. ^ a b c In Highest median, Ranked Pairs, and Schulze voting, there is always a regret-free, semi-honest ballot for any voter, holding all other ballots constant and assuming they know enough about how others will vote. Under such circumstances, there is always at least one way for a voter to participate without grading any less-preferred candidate above any more-preferred one.
  6. ^ a b A variant of Minimax that counts only pairwise opposition, not opposition minus support, fails the Condorcet criterion and meets later-no-harm.
  7. ^ A randomly chosen ballot determines winner. This and closely related methods are of mathematical interest and included here to demonstrate that even unreasonable methods can pass voting method criteria.
  8. ^ Where a winner is randomly chosen from the candidates, sortition is included to demonstrate that even non-voting methods can pass some criteria.


The main difference between the Schulze method and the ranked pairs method can be seen in this example:

Suppose the MinMax score of a set X of candidates is the strength of the strongest pairwise win of a candidate A ∉ X against a candidate B ∈ X. Then the Schulze method, but not Ranked Pairs, guarantees that the winner is always a candidate of the set with minimum MinMax score.[2]: §4.8  So, in some sense, the Schulze method minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed when determining the winner.

On the other hand, Ranked Pairs minimizes the largest majority that has to be reversed to determine the order of finish, in the MinLexMax sense.[citation needed][4] In other words, when Ranked Pairs and the Schulze method produce different orders of finish, for the majorities on which the two orders of finish disagree, the Schulze order reverses a larger majority than the Ranked Pairs order.

History

The Schulze method was developed by Markus Schulze in 1997. It was first discussed in public mailing lists in 1997–1998[5] and in 2000.[6]

In 2011, Schulze published the method in the academic journal Social Choice and Welfare.[2]

Usage

Sample ballot for Wikimedia's Board of Trustees elections

Government

The Schulze method is used by the city of Silla for all referendums.[7][8] It is also used by the cities of Turin and San Donà di Piave and by the London Borough of Southwark through their use of the WeGovNow platform, which in turn uses the LiquidFeedback decision tool.[citation needed]

Political parties

Schulze was adopted by the Pirate Party of Sweden (2009),[9] and the Pirate Party of Germany (2010).[10] The Boise, Idaho chapter of the Democratic Socialists of America in February chose this method for their first special election held in March 2018.[11]

Student government and associations

Organizations

It is used by the Institute of Electrical and Electronics Engineers, by the Association for Computing Machinery, and by USENIX through their use of the HotCRP decision tool.

Organizations which currently use the Schulze method include:

Notes

  1. ^ Markus Schulze, "A new monotonic, clone-independent, reversal symmetric, and Condorcet-consistent single-winner election method", Social Choice and Welfare, volume 36, number 2, page 267–303, 2011. Preliminary version in Voting Matters, 17:9-19, 2003.
  2. ^ a b c d e f g h i j k l m n Markus Schulze, "A new monotonic, clone-independent, reversal symmetric, and condorcet-consistent single-winner election method", Social Choice and Welfare, volume 36, number 2, page 267–303, 2011. Preliminary version in Voting Matters, 17:9-19, 2003.
  3. ^ a b c Douglas R. Woodall, Properties of Preferential Election Rules, Voting Matters, issue 3, pages 8–15, December 1994
  4. ^ Tideman, T. Nicolaus, "Independence of clones as a criterion for voting rules", Social Choice and Welfare vol 4 #3 (1987), pp. 185–206.
  5. ^ See:
  6. ^ See:
  7. ^ Hortanoticias, Redacción (2016-02-23). "Al voltant de 2.000 participants en dos dies en la primera enquesta popular de Silla que decidirà sobre espectacles taurins". Hortanoticias.com (in Spanish). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  8. ^ Silla, ~ El Cresol de (2016-05-26). "Un any d'aprofundiment democràtic a Silla". El Cresol de Silla (in Catalan). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  9. ^ a b See:
  10. ^ a b 11 of the 16 regional sections and the federal section of the Pirate Party of Germany are using LiquidFeedback for unbinding internal opinion polls. In 2010/2011, the Pirate Parties of Neukölln (link), Mitte (link), Steglitz-Zehlendorf (link), Lichtenberg (link), and Tempelhof-Schöneberg (link) adopted the Schulze method for its primaries. Furthermore, the Pirate Party of Berlin (in 2011) (link) and the Pirate Party of Regensburg (in 2012) (link) adopted this method for their primaries.
  11. ^ Chumich, Andrew. "DSA Special Election". Retrieved 2018-02-25.
  12. ^ Campobasso. Comunali, scattano le primarie a 5 Stelle, February 2014
  13. ^ Macaro, Mirko (2015-03-03). "Fondi, il punto sui candidati a sindaco. Certezze, novità e colpi di scena". h24 notizie - portale indipendente di news dalla provincia (in Italian). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  14. ^ article 25(5) of the bylaws, October 2013
  15. ^ "MoVimento 5 Stelle - Montemurlo: 2° Step Comunarie di Montemurlo". November 2013. Archived from the original on 2015-04-02. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  16. ^ article 12 of the bylaws, January 2015
  17. ^ Ridefinizione della lista di San Cesareo con Metodo Schulze, February 2014
  18. ^ "National Congress 2011 Results – Pirate Party Australia". pirateparty.org.au. 18 November 2011. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  19. ^ §6(10) of the bylaws
  20. ^ Article III.3.4 of the Statutory Rules (french, dutch)
  21. ^ Píratar (2013-10-23). "Schulze aðferðin". Píratar (in Icelandic). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  22. ^ Rules adopted on 18 December 2011
  23. ^ Pontier, Matthijs (2015-01-11). "Verslag ledenraadpleging 4 januari". Piratenpartij Noord Holland (in Dutch). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  24. ^ Pankerl, Florian (2010-09-18). "Piratenversammlung der Piratenpartei Schweiz 2010 – Samstag" (in German). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  25. ^ article IV section 3 of the bylaws, July 2012
  26. ^ §10 III of its bylaws, June 2013
  27. ^ The Board of Directors of Volt Europe in Spain. "Algunas consideraciones sobre en qué grupo estará Volt Europa en el Parlamento Europeo" [Some considerations on which group Volt Europe will join in the European Parliament]. Medium (in Spanish). Archived from the original on 20 August 2024.
  28. ^ Hajdu, Tekla (2017-09-24). "The Schulze Method – Agora 101". The AEGEEan - AEGEE's online magazine - AEGEE-Europe. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  29. ^ Voting Details, January 2021
  30. ^ Référendum sur la réforme du thurnage, June 2021
  31. ^ article 57 of the statutory rules
  32. ^ "User Voting Instructions". Gso.cs.binghamton.edu. Archived from the original on 2013-09-09. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  33. ^ "Hillegass-Parker House Bylaws § 5. Elections". Hillegass-Parker House website. Retrieved 4 October 2015.
  34. ^ See:
  35. ^ article 9.4.5.h of the charter, November 2017
  36. ^ Ajith, Van Atta win ASG election, April 2013
  37. ^ §6 and §7 of its bylaws, May 2014
  38. ^ §6(6) of the bylaws
  39. ^ Election of the Annodex Association committee for 2007, February 2007
  40. ^ §9a of the bylaws, October 2013
  41. ^ See:
    • 2013 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2014
    • 2014 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2015
    • 2015 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, March 2016
    • 2016 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, January 2017
    • 2017 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, February 2018
    • 2018 Golden Geek Awards - Nominations Open, March 2019
  42. ^ article 7(e)(iii)(2) of the charter, May 2021
  43. ^ Adam Helman, Family Affair Voting Scheme - Schulze Method
  44. ^ Steering and Technical committee, November 2021
  45. ^ See:
  46. ^ "Guidance Document". Eudec.org. 2009-11-15. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  47. ^ Democratic election of the server admins Archived 2015-10-02 at the Wayback Machine, July 2010
  48. ^ Voters Guide, September 2011
  49. ^ Project:Elections
  50. ^ "CIVS Election Results: GnuPG Logo Vote". 2013-10-03. Archived from the original on 2013-10-03. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  51. ^ Haskell Logo Competition, March 2009
  52. ^ Article 6 Section 2 of the Constitution, February 2021
  53. ^ section 9.4.7.3 of the Operating Procedures of the Address Council of the Address Supporting Organization (archived from source 2023-06-06)
  54. ^ "A club by any other name..." Kanawha Valley Scrabble Club. 2009-04-02. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  55. ^ section 3.4.1 of the Rules of Procedures for Online Voting
  56. ^ Knight Foundation awards $5000 to best created-on-the-spot projects, June 2009
  57. ^ Kubernetes Community, Kubernetes, 2022-09-24, retrieved 2022-09-24
  58. ^ "Kumoricon – Mascot Contest". Kumoricon. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  59. ^ article 8.3 of the bylaws
  60. ^ The Principles of LiquidFeedback. Berlin: Interaktive Demokratie e. V. 2014. ISBN 978-3-00-044795-2.
  61. ^ "Madisonium Bylaws - Adopted". Google Docs.
  62. ^ "Wahlmodus" (in German). Metalab.at. Retrieved 2010-05-08.
  63. ^ David Chandler, Voting for more than just either-or, MIT Tech Talk, volume 52, number 19, page 2, 12 March 2008
  64. ^ See:
  65. ^ "2009 Director Elections". noisebridge.net.
  66. ^ "Online Voting Policy". openembedded.org.
  67. ^ ONNX Steering Committee election guideline
  68. ^ "OpenStack Election — OpenStack Governance". governance.openstack.org. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  69. ^ Mark, Atwood (May 25, 2016). "[Partners] text of OpenSwitch Project Charter 2016-05-03". Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  70. ^ "Committee Elections 2012". rllmuk. 10 April 2012. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  71. ^ Squeak Oversight Board Election 2010, March 2010
  72. ^ See:
  73. ^ "[IAEP] Election status update". lists.sugarlabs.org. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  74. ^ Minutes of the 2018 Annual Sverok Meeting, November 2018
  75. ^ "2007 TopCoder Collegiate Challenge". community.topcoder.com. Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  76. ^ Bell, Alan (May 17, 2012). "Ubuntu IRC Council Position". Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  77. ^ "/v/GAs - Pairwise voting results". vidyagaemawards.com.
  78. ^ See:
  79. ^ "Wikipédia:Prise de décision/Choix dans les votes", Wikipédia (in French), 2019-08-22, retrieved 2022-09-24
  80. ^ "Pages liées à Méthode Schulze". fr.wikipedia.org (in French). Retrieved 2022-09-24.
  81. ^ "ויקיפדיה:פרלמנט/הכרעה" [Wikipedia:Parliament/Decisionmaking]. he.wikipedia.org (in Hebrew).
  82. ^ See e.g. here [1] (May 2009), here [2] (August 2009), and here [3] (December 2009).
  83. ^ See here and here.
  84. ^ Девятнадцатые выборы арбитров, второй тур [Result of Arbitration Committee Elections]. kalan.cc (in Russian). Archived from the original on 2015-02-22.
  85. ^ See here

Read other articles:

History of LGBT people and Mormonism in the 1980s See also: Brigham Young University LGBT history, Homosexuality and The Church of Jesus Christ of Latter-day Saints, Gender minorities and the LDS church, Sexuality and Mormonism, and LGBT Mormon people and organizations LGBT Mormon topics Overview articles Homosexuality & the LDS Church Gender minorities & the LDS church LGBT Mormon people & organizations BYU LGBT history LGBT Mormon suicides LGBT rights & the LDS Church LGBT r...

Чжао Мэнфу, Чжао Юн, Чжао Линь Кони и конюхи (фрагмент авторства Чжао Мэнфу). 1296—1359 元 趙孟頫 趙雍 趙麟 吳興趙氏三世人馬圖 卷 Бумага, чернила. 30,2 × 178,1 см Метрополитен-музей, Нью-Йорк (инв. 1988.135) «Кони и конюхи» (кит. трад. 元 趙孟頫 趙雍 趙麟 吳興趙氏三世人馬圖 卷) — рукописный с...

Cet article est une ébauche concernant un physicien américain. Vous pouvez partager vos connaissances en l’améliorant (comment ?) selon les recommandations des projets correspondants. Pour les articles homonymes, voir Morley. Edward MorleyEdward MorleyBiographieNaissance 29 janvier 1838NewarkDécès 24 février 1923 (à 85 ans)West HartfordNom de naissance Edward Williams MorleyNationalité américaineFormation Williams CollegeUniversité Case Western ReserveActivités Physicie...

Штрауб: Бруно Штрауб (угор. Straub Ferenc Brunó); 1914 — 1996) — угорський біохімік і політик. Рамона Штрауб (нім. Ramona Straub); нар. 1993) — німецька стрибунка з трампліна, чемпіонка світу. Юрген Штрауб (нім. Jürgen Straub; 1953) — німецький легкоатлет, олімпійський медаліст. 6147 Штрауб Штрауб

Reservoir in Contra Costa County, CaliforniaLos Vaqueros ReservoirAerial view from the southeastLos Vaqueros ReservoirShow map of CaliforniaLos Vaqueros ReservoirShow map of the United StatesLocationDiablo Range,Contra Costa County, CaliforniaCoordinates37°49′13″N 121°44′02″W / 37.82025°N 121.7338°W / 37.82025; -121.7338TypereservoirBasin countriesUnited StatesMax. length2.5 mi (4.0 km)Max. width2.5 mi (4.0 km)Surface area1,400 acre...

Bahlui RiverBahlui River in IaşiLokasi di RumaniaLokasiNegaraRumaniaKotaHârlău, IaşiDistrikBotoşani County,Iaşi CountyCiri-ciri fisikHulu sungai  - lokasiTudora - elevasi500 meter (1.600 ft) Muara sungaiJijia River - lokasiChipereştiPanjang119 meter (390 ft)Debit air  - rata-rata28 meter kubik per detik (990 cu ft/s) Daerah Aliran SungaiLuas DASDAS: 2007Official River CodeXIII.15.32 Sungai Bahlui adalah sungai terbes...

Logo des Festivals Das San Francisco International Film Festival (SFIFF) in San Francisco ist mit fünfzehn Tagen Dauer eines der am längsten durchgängig veranstalteten internationalen Filmfestivals der Vereinigten Staaten. Es wird seit 1957 jährlich von der San Francisco Film Society veranstaltet und findet zwei Wochen lang im Frühjahr statt. Gezeigt werden um die 200 Filme aus mehr als 50 Ländern, darunter vor allem Produktionen, die in den Vereinigten Staaten noch nicht veröffentlich...

Attorney general for the U.S. state of Washington Attorney General of WashingtonIncumbentBob Fergusonsince January 16, 2013Office of the Attorney GeneralStyleThe HonorableTerm lengthFour yearsNo limitConstituting instrumentWashington State ConstitutionFormation1887 The attorney general of Washington is the chief legal officer of the U.S. state of Washington and head of the Washington State Office of the Attorney General. The attorney general represents clients of the state and defends th...

You can help expand this article with text translated from the corresponding article in Danish. Click [show] for important translation instructions. Machine translation, like DeepL or Google Translate, is a useful starting point for translations, but translators must revise errors as necessary and confirm that the translation is accurate, rather than simply copy-pasting machine-translated text into the English Wikipedia. Do not translate text that appears unreliable or low-quality. If possibl...

Private, coeducational school in Long Beach, United StatesSt. Anthony High SchoolAddress620 Olive AvenueLong Beach 90802United StatesCoordinates33°46′30″N 118°10′56″W / 33.77500°N 118.18222°W / 33.77500; -118.18222InformationTypePrivate, CoeducationalMottoSpes Nostra(Our Hope)Religious affiliation(s)Roman CatholicPatron saint(s)St. Anthony of PaduaEstablished1920OversightArchdiocese of Los AngelesPresidentChristine TuckerPrincipalAdan JaramilloTeaching staf...

Vincenzo LanciaVincenzo LanciaLahirVincenzo Lancia(1881-08-24)24 Agustus 1881 Fobello, Piedmont, Kerajaan ItaliaMeninggal15 Februari 1937(1937-02-15) (umur 55) Turin, Kerajaan ItaliaPekerjaanPembalap, insinyur dan pendiri LanciaSuami/istriAdele MigliettiAnakAnna Maria Lancia Gianni Lancia Eleonora Lancia Vincenzo Lancia (24 Agustus 1881 – 15 Februari 1937) adalah seorang pembalap Italia, insinyur dan pendiri Lancia. Vincenzo Lancia lahir di desa kecil Fobello pada 24 Agus...

Інститут ядерних проблем Білоруського державного університету Основні дані Засновано 1986 Абревіатура НДІ ЯП БДУ Розташування  Білорусь: МінськКраїна  БілорусьАдреса ул. Бобруйська 11, Мінськ, 220030, БілорусьТип науково-дослідний інститутШтат працівників 117 осіб...

Fresno mayoral election, 2016 ← 2012 June 7, 2016 (first round)[1]November 8, 2016 (runoff) 2020 →   Candidate Lee Brand Henry R. Perea H. Spees First-round vote 25,491 37,006 15,089 First-round percentage 30.79% 44.70% 18.23 Second-round vote 71,776 68,053 Second-round percentage 51.20% 47.54% Mayor before election Ashley Swearengin Elected Mayor Lee Brand Elections in California Federal government U.S. President 1852 1856 1860 1864 1868 1872 1876 1880 1884...

World Deaf Athletics ChampionshipsStatusactiveGenresports eventDate(s)midyearFrequency4 YearsInaugurated2008Organised byCISS The World Deaf Athletics Championships is a quadrennial global competitions in the sport of athletics for deaf people. It is organised by the International Committee of Sports for the Deaf and was first held in 2008.[1] Editions Outdoor Edition Year Venue Place Country Dates Events Athletes Teams Ref 1 2008 İzmir Atatürk Stadium İzmir  Turkey 22–29 Sep...

Brand of malt liquor Olde English 800Olde English 800 - 40ozManufacturerMiller Brewing Company (since 1999)Introduced1964Alcohol by volume 5.9–8.0StyleMalt Liquor Olde English 800 is a brand of American malt liquor brewed by the Miller Brewing Company. It was introduced in 1964, and has been produced by the company since 1999.[1] It is available in a variety of serving sizes including, since the late 1980s,[2] a 40-U.S.-fluid-ounce (1,200-milliliter) bottle. History Int...

Jembatan Lama KediriFoto Jembatan Lama yang dipotret sebelum tahun 1922Koordinat7°48′50″S 112°0′26.65″E / 7.81389°S 112.0074028°E / -7.81389; 112.0074028Moda transportasiKendaraan R2, dan pejalan kakiMelintasiSungai BrantasLokalKota Kediri, Jawa TimurNama resmiJembatan Brug Over den Brantas te KediriKarakteristikDesainJembatan besiBahan bakuBesiPanjang total160 mLebar5.80 mTinggi7.50 mSejarahMulai dibangun1855Selesai dibangun1869Lokasi Jembatan Brug Over de...

State highway in Iowa, United States Iowa Highway 37Iowa 37 highlighted in redRoute informationMaintained by Iowa DOTLength40.231 mi[1] (64.746 km)Major junctionsWest end Iowa 175 near TurinMajor intersections US 30 in DunlapEast end US 59 near Earling LocationCountryUnited StatesStateIowaCounties Monona Crawford Harrison Shelby Highway system Iowa Primary Highway System Interstate US State Secondary Scenic ← I-35→ Iowa 38 Iowa Highway ...

Species of bird Tylas vanga Conservation status Least Concern (IUCN 3.1)[1] Scientific classification Domain: Eukaryota Kingdom: Animalia Phylum: Chordata Class: Aves Order: Passeriformes Family: Vangidae Genus: TylasHartlaub, 1862 Species: T. eduardi Binomial name Tylas eduardiHartlaub, 1862 The tylas vanga (Tylas eduardi) is a species of bird in the family Vangidae. It is monotypic within the genus Tylas.[2] It is endemic to Madagascar. Its natural habitats are sub...

Esta página cita fontes, mas que não cobrem todo o conteúdo. Ajude a inserir referências. Conteúdo não verificável pode ser removido.—Encontre fontes: ABW  • CAPES  • Google (N • L • A) (Junho de 2019) Banpará Banco do Estado do Pará Razão social Banco do Estado do Pará S.A. Tipo Empresa de capital aberto Slogan Onde tem Pará, tem Banpará Cotação B3: BPAR3 Atividade Serviços financeiros Gênero Sociedade de e...

This article is written like a personal reflection, personal essay, or argumentative essay that states a Wikipedia editor's personal feelings or presents an original argument about a topic. Please help improve it by rewriting it in an encyclopedic style. (August 2015) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Sacred Love Versus Profane Love (1602–03) by Giovanni Baglione. Part of a series onLoveRed-outline heart icon Types of love Affection Bonding Broken heart Compassionate love...

Kembali kehalaman sebelumnya