Land reform

Farmers protesting for land reform in Indonesia, 2004

Land reform (also known as agrarian reform) involving the changing of laws, regulations, or customs regarding land ownership, land use, and land transfers.[1][2] The reforms may be initiated by governments, by interested groups, or by revolution.[3]

Land reform is often considered a contentious process, as land is a key driver of a wide range of social, political and economic outcomes.[4][5] The structure and distribution of land rights has been linked to state formation, economic growth, inequality, political violence, and identity politics, making land reform highly consequential for the long-term structures of society.[4]

Overview

Land reform may consist of a government-initiated or government-backed property redistribution, generally of agricultural land. Land reform can, therefore, refer to transfer of ownership from the more powerful to the less powerful, such as from a relatively small number of wealthy or noble owners with extensive land holdings (e.g., plantations, large ranches, or agribusiness plots) to individual ownership by those who work the land.[6] Such transfers of ownership may be with or without compensation; compensation may vary from token amounts to the full value of the land.[7]

Land reform may also entail the transfer of land from individual ownership—even peasant ownership in smallholdings—to government-owned collective farms; it has also, in other times and places, referred to the exact opposite: division of government-owned collective farms into smallholdings.[8] The common characteristic of all land reforms is modification or replacement of existing institutional arrangements governing possession and use of land. Thus, while land reform may be radical in nature, such as through large-scale transfers of land from one group to another, it can also be less dramatic, such as regulatory reforms aimed at improving land administration.[9]

Land usage and tenure

Land ownership and tenure can be perceived as controversial in part because ideas defining what it means to access or control land, such as through "land ownership" or "land tenure", can vary considerably across regions and even within countries.[10] Land reforms, which change what it means to control land, therefore create tensions and conflicts between those who lose and those who gain from these redefinitions (see next section).[11]

Western conceptions of land have evolved over the past several centuries to place greater emphasis on individual land ownership, formalized through documents such as land titles.[12] Control over land may also be perceived less in terms of individual ownership and more in terms of land use, or through what is known as land tenure.[13] Historically, in many parts of Africa for example, land was not owned by an individual, but rather used by an extended family or a village community. Different people in a family or community had different rights to access this land for different purposes and at different times. Such rights were often conveyed through oral history and not formally documented.[14]

These different ideas of land ownership and tenure are sometimes referred to using different terminology. For example, "formal" or "statutory" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with individual land ownership. "Informal" or "customary" land systems refer to ideas of land control more closely affiliated with land tenure.[15]

Terms dictating control over and use of land can therefore take many forms. Some specific examples of present-day or historic forms of formal and informal land ownership include:

  • Traditional land tenure, as practiced by the indigenous tribes of Pre-Columbian North America.
  • Feudal land ownership, through fiefdoms
  • Life estate, interest in real property that ends at death.
  • Fee tail, hereditary, non-transferable ownership of real property.
  • Fee simple. Under common law, this is the most complete ownership interest one can have in real property.
  • Leasehold or rental
  • Rights to use a common
  • Sharecropping
  • Run rig and rundale
  • Well-Field System
  • Easements
  • Kibbutz and moshav
  • Satoyama
  • Agricultural labor – under which someone works the land in exchange for money, payment in kind, or some combination of the two
  • Collective ownership
  • Access to land through a membership in a cooperative, or shares in a corporation, which owns the land (typically by fee simple or its equivalent, but possibly under other arrangements).
  • Government collectives, such as those that might be found in communist states, whereby government ownership of most agricultural land is combined in various ways with tenure for farming collectives.

Motivation

Land reform is a deeply political process[16] and therefore many arguments for and against it have emerged. These arguments vary tremendously over time and place. In the twentieth century, many land reforms emerged from a particular political ideology, such as communism or socialism. In the 19th century in colonized states, a colonial government may have changed the laws dictating land ownership to better consolidate political power or to support its colonial economy.[17] In more recent times, electoral mobilization and the use of land as a patronage resource have been proposed as possible motivations for land reform efforts, such as the extensive redistributive land reforms of Robert Mugabe in Zimbabwe.[18]

Arguments for

Arguments in support of land reform focus on its potential social and economic benefits, particularly in developing countries, that may emerge from reforms focused on greater land formalization. Such benefits may include eradicating food insecurity and alleviating rural poverty.[19]

And the great owners, who must lose their land in an upheaval, the great owners with access to history, with eyes to read history and to know the great fact: when property accumulates in too few hands it is taken away. And that companion fact: when a majority of the people are hungry and cold they will take by force what they need. And the little screaming fact that sounds through all history: repression works only to strengthen and knit the repressed.

Arguments in support of such reforms gained particular momentum after the publication of The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else by Peruvian economist Hernando de Soto in 2000. The poor, he argues, are often unable to secure formal property rights, such as land titles, to the land on which they live or farm because of poor governance, corruption and/or overly complex bureaucracies. Without land titles or other formal documentation of their land assets, they are less able to access formal credit. Political and legal reforms within countries, according to de Soto, will help to include the poor in formal legal and economic systems, increase the poor's ability to access credit and contribute to economic growth and poverty reduction.[21]

Many international development organizations and bilateral and multilateral donors, such as the World Bank, have embraced de Soto's ideas, or similar ideas, about the benefits of greater formalized land rights.[22] This has translated into a number of development programs that work with governments and civil society organizations to initiate and implement land reforms.[23] Evidence to support the economic and pro-poor benefits of increased formalized land rights are still inconclusive according to some critics (see "Arguments against land reform" below).

Other arguments in support of land reform point to the need to alleviate conflicting land laws, particularly in former colonies, where formal and informal land systems may exist in tension with each other.[24] Such conflicts can make marginalized groups vulnerable to further exploitation.[25] For example, in many countries in Africa with conflicting land laws, AIDS stigmatization has led to an increasing number of AIDS widows being kicked off marital land by in-laws.[26] While the woman may have both customary and statutory rights to the land, confusion over which set of laws has primacy, or even a lack of knowledge of relevant laws, leave many AIDS widows at a significant disadvantage. Also, conflicting formal and informal land laws can also clog a country's legal system, making it prone to corruption.[27]

Additional arguments for land reform focus on the potential environmental benefits of reform. For example, if reform leads to greater security of land ownership, through either formal or informal means, then those that use the land will be better stewards of it.[28]

Land reforms carried out in Japan, Taiwan and South Korea are credited with contributing to the industrial development. The equitable distribution of land led to increasing agricultural outputs, high rural purchasing power and social mobility.[29]

Arguments against

Many of the arguments in support of land reform speak to its potentially positive social and economic outcomes. Yet, as mentioned previously, land reform is an intensely political process.[11] Thus, many of those opposed to land reform are nervous as to the underlying motivations of those initiating the reform. For example, some may fear that they will be disadvantaged or victimized as a result of the reforms. Others may fear that they will lose out in the economic and political power struggles (especially in under developed countries) that underlie many land reforms.[30]

Other groups and individuals express concerns about land reforms focused on formalization of property rights. While the economic and social benefits of formalized land rights are often touted, some research suggests that such reforms are either ineffective or may cause further hardship or conflict.[31]

Additional arguments against land reform focus on concerns over equity issues and potential elite capture of land, particularly in regards to reforms focused on greater land formalization. If improperly or inadequately implemented, critics worry that such reforms may further disadvantage marginalized groups such as indigenous communities or women.[32] These concerns also lead to questions about the institutional capacity of governments to implement land reforms as they are designed. Even if a country does have this capacity, critics worry that corruption and patrimonialism will lead to further elite capture.[33]

In looking at more radical reforms, such as large-scale land redistribution, arguments against reform include concerns that redistributed land will not be used productively and that owners of expropriated land will not be compensated adequately or compensated at all. Zimbabwe, again, is a commonly cited example of the perils of such large-scale reforms, whereby land redistribution contributed to economic decline and increased food insecurity in the country.[34] In cases where land reform has been enacted as part of socialist collectivization, many of the arguments against collectivization more generally apply.

National efforts

An early example of land reform was the Irish Land Acts of 1870–1909. Most all newly independent countries of Eastern and Central Europe implemented land reforms in the aftermath of World War I. In most countries, the land in excess of certain limits (20–500 ha (49–1,236 acres), depending on the region and type of land) was expropriated; in Finland, it was redeemed and placed into a special fund.[35]

See also

References

  1. ^ Batty, Fodei Joseph. "Pressures from Above, Below and Both Directions: The Politics of Land Reform in South Africa, Brazil and Zimbabwe". Western Michigan University. Presented at the Annual Meeting of the Midwest Political Science Association. Chicago, Illinois. April 7–10, 2005. p. 3. [1]
  2. ^ "Land Reform - an overview | ScienceDirect Topics". www.sciencedirect.com. Retrieved 2024-12-11.
  3. ^ "land reform". www.britannica.com. 2024-11-06.
  4. ^ a b Albertus, Michael; Klaus, Kathleen (2025). "Land and Politics". Annual Review of Political Science. doi:10.1146/annurev-polisci-040623-112955. ISSN 1094-2939.
  5. ^ Lund, Christian. Local Politics and the Dynamics of Property in Africa. Cambridge University Press: New York. 2008.
  6. ^ Borras, Saturnino M. Jr. "The Philippine Land form in Comparative Perspective: Some conceptual and Methodological Implications". Journal of Agrarian Change. 6,1 (January 2006): 69–101.
  7. ^ Adams, Martin and J. Howell. "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa". Overseas Development Institute. DFID. Natural Resources Perspectives No. 64. January 2001. [2] Archived 2009-12-05 at the Wayback Machine
  8. ^ Adams, Martin and J. Howell. "Redistributive Land Reform in Southern Africa". Archived 2009-12-05 at the Wayback Machine Overseas Development Institute. DFID. Natural Resources Perspectives No. 64. January 2001.
  9. ^ Ghana's Land Administration Project Archived 2011-07-21 at the Wayback Machine
  10. ^ La Croix, Sumner. "Land Tenure: An Introduction". Working Paper no. 02-13. May 2002. University of Hawaii.
  11. ^ a b Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." African Affairs. 2007. 106: 557–586.
  12. ^ Locke, John. Two Treatises of Government. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. [1689] 1991. and Smith, Adam. The Wealth of Nations. Books 1—III. London: Penguin Books. 1999.
  13. ^ "What is land tenure?" Food and Agriculture Organization.
  14. ^ Dekker, Henri A.L. The Invisible Line: Land Reform, Land Tenure Security and Land Registration. Ashgate: Burlington, 2003. p. 2.
  15. ^ "Land Law." Law and Development. The World Bank. February 23, 2007. [3],
  16. ^ : Boone, Catherine. "Property and Constitutional Order: Land Tenure reform and the Future of the African State." African Affairs. 2007. 106: 557–86. and Manji, Ambreena. The Politics of Land Reform in Ghana: From Communal Tenure to Free Markets. Zed Books: New York. 2006.
  17. ^ Berry, Sata. "Debating the land question in Africa." Johns Hopkins University. N.d. "Archived copy" (PDF). Archived from the original (PDF) on 2012-01-13. Retrieved 2010-12-02.{{cite web}}: CS1 maint: archived copy as title (link)
  18. ^ Boone, Catherine and N. Kriger. "Multiparty elections and land patronage: Zimbabwe and Cote d'Ivoire." Commonwealth and Comparative Politics. 48,1 (April 2010): 173–202.
  19. ^ Meinzen-Dick, Ruth, Markelova, Helen and Moore, Kelsey. "The Role of Collective Action and Property Rights in Climate Change Strategies." International Food Policy Research Institute (IFPRI), 2010. and Economic Commission for Africa. "Land Tenure Systems and their Impacts on Food security and Sustainable Development in Africa." 2009.
  20. ^ The Grapes of Wrath, by John Steinbeck, Penguin, 2006, 0143039431, pg 238
  21. ^ De Soto, Hernando. The Mystery of Capital: Why Capitalism Triumphs in the West and Fails Everywhere Else. New York: Basic Books. 2000.
  22. ^ Deininger, Klaus W. Land Policies for Growth and Poverty Reduction. The World Bank. 2003. [4]
  23. ^ World Bank. "Regional Study on Land Administration, Land Markets, and Collateralized Lending." 2003. [5]
  24. ^ Moore, Jina. "Africa's continental divide: land disputes." Christian Science Monitor. January 30, 2010. [6]
  25. ^ Kafmbe, Anthony Luyirika. "Access to Justice: Widows and the Institutions Regulating Succession to Property in Uganda." Human Rights Review; Jul2006, Vol. 7 Issue 4, pp. 100–113.
  26. ^ Ambasa-Shisanya, Constance. "Widowhood in the Era of HIV/AIDS: A Case Study of the Slaya District, Kenya." Journal of Social Aspects of HIV/AIDS. August 2007. 2:2, 606–615.
  27. ^ Tettey, Wisdom, B. Gebe and K. Ansah-Koi. "The Politics of Land and Land-related Conflicts in Ghana: A Summary." Land Policy Reform Project. Institute for Statistical, Social and Economic Research at the University of Ghana. 2008. [7] Archived 2020-03-07 at the Wayback Machine
  28. ^ World Resources Institute. "The Wealth of the Poor: Managing Ecosystems to Fight Poverty." 2005. "World Resources 2005 -- the Wealth of the Poor: Managing ecosystems to fight poverty | World Resources Institute". Archived from the original on 2011-08-07. Retrieved 2010-12-02. and Food and Agriculture Organization of the United Nations (FAO). "Land Tenure and Rural Development." FAO Land Tenure Studies No. 3. 2002. Accessed August 21, 2010. Available: [8][permanent dead link]
  29. ^ "Land: The Triumph of Gardening". How Asia Works: Success and Failure in the World's Most Dynamic Region. Grove Press. 2014. ISBN 9780802121325.
  30. ^ "A chance to improve how Kenya is run." The Economist. July 29, 2010
  31. ^ Bourbeau, Heather, "Property Wrongs." Foreign Policy. Nov/Dec 2001. Issue 127, pp. 78–79 and Nyamu Musembi, Celestine. "De Soto and Land Relations in rural Africa: breathing life into dead theories about property rights." Third World Quarterly. 2007. 28:8, 1457–1478.
  32. ^ Drimie, Scott. "The Impact of HIV/AIDS on Land: Case Studies from Kenya, Lesotho and South Africa." Food and Agriculture Organization. August 2002. and Varley, Ann. "Gender and Property Formalization: Conventional and Alternative Approaches." World Development. October 2007. 35:10, 1739–1753.
  33. ^ Gender in Agriculture Source Book. The World Bank, FAO and IFAD. 2009.[9]
  34. ^ "From breadbasket to basket case." The Economist. June 27, 2002
  35. ^ Gediminas Vaskela. The Land Reform of 1919–1940: Lithuania and the Countries of East and Central Europe Archived 2012-03-22 at the Wayback Machine

Further reading

Read other articles:

Bridge in Florence, Italy You can help expand this article with text translated from the corresponding article in Italian. (January 2023) Click [show] for important translation instructions. Machine translation, like DeepL or Google Translate, is a useful starting point for translations, but translators must revise errors as necessary and confirm that the translation is accurate, rather than simply copy-pasting machine-translated text into the English Wikipedia. Do not translate text tha...

 

  لمعانٍ أخرى، طالع ويليام هاربر (توضيح). ويليام هاربر (بالإنجليزية: William Harper)‏    معلومات شخصية الميلاد 17 يناير 1790[1]  أنتيغوا  الوفاة 10 أكتوبر 1847 (57 سنة)   كارولاينا الجنوبية  مواطنة الولايات المتحدة  مناصب عضو مجلس الشيوخ الأمريكي[2]   عضو خلال

 

Brésil Primeira ascensão Descrição País de origem França Fabricante Lachambre & Machuron Quantidade produzida 1 Primeiro voo em 4 de julho de 1898 (125 anos) Especificações Dimensões Volume 113 m³ (3 990 ft³) Peso(s) Peso vazio 27,5 kg (60,6 lb) Aviso Brésil foi o primeiro balão esférico desenvolvido por Alberto Santos Dumont, onde, aos 25 anos, apresentou diversas inovações na área da aeronáutica e realizou mais de 200 voos. ...

Statue of Sigismund by Péter Gáspár (2003) in the Europe Place, Komárno Sigismund, Holy Roman Emperor, from the House of Luxembourg, was the holder of five European royal crowns (Germany, Hungary, Croatia, Bohemia, Italy, thus an imperial association stretching from the North and Baltic Seas to the Mediterranean and the Black Seas) in his lifetime and played an important role in the history of East-Central Europe.[1] For a long time though, technical difficulties like linguistic b...

 

Category of Japanese city (Circle click-able)■ ― Designated cities■ ― Core cities■ ― Special cities Administrative divisionsof Japan Prefectural Prefectures Sub-prefectural Subprefectures Municipal Designated cities Core cities Special cities Cities (List) Special wards (Tokyo) Towns Villages Sub-municipal Wards vte A core city (中核市, Chūkakushi) is a class or category of Japanese cities. It is a local administrative division created by the national government.[1] Co...

 

Опис файлу Опис Фазова площина стандартного відображення Чирікова Джерело Час створення 04.06.2008 Автор зображення Did Panas Ліцензія GFDL У цього зображення немає: інформації про джерело Якщо ви маєте таку інформацію чи маєте до неї доступ, будь ласка, додайте її на сторінку опи...

Este artículo o sección necesita referencias que aparezcan en una publicación acreditada.Este aviso fue puesto el 28 de noviembre de 2019. Al pie del Vísquer, la antigua montaña amurallada se abre a la ciudad de Játiva, capital de la comarca de La Costera (Valencia), un ejemplo de población concentrada. Concentración de la población se refiere al proceso de aumento de la población de los pueblos más grandes a expensas de los más pequeños. especialmente, en las áreas rurales. Y l...

 

Pokémon:The Electric Tale of Pikachu電撃!ピカチュウ(Dengeki! Pikachū) MangaPengarangToshihiro OnoPenerbitShogakukanPenerbit bahasa InggrisNA Viz MediaSG Chuang YiMajalahCoroCoro ComicDemografiAnak-anakTerbitApril 1997 – Desember 1999Volume4  Portal anime dan manga Pokémon Graphic Novel, lebih dikenal sebagai Pokemon: Kisah Listrik Pikachu (電撃!ピカチュウcode: ja is deprecated , Dengeki! Pikachū, Electric Shock! Pikachu) adalah seri manga Jepang yang dibuat oleh...

 

O empresário Joesley Batista, dono da JBS e pivô do escândalo, deixa a superintendência da Polícia Federal após prestar depoimento, em agosto de 2017. As delações da JBS na Operação Lava Jato referem-se ao acordo de leniência firmado entre a empresa JBS e a Procuradoria-Geral da República (PGR) em abril de 2017, no âmbito da Operação Lava Jato. O Supremo Tribunal Federal (STF) homologou o acordo em 18 de maio de 2017 a partir da delação premiada dos proprietários Joesley e W...

اضغط هنا للاطلاع على كيفية قراءة التصنيف الليمون الياباني Malayan kumquat foliage and fruit المرتبة التصنيفية نوع  التصنيف العلمي النطاق: حقيقيات النوى المملكة: نباتات الشعيبة: بذريات غير مصنف: كاسيات البذور غير مصنف: ثنائيات الفلقة الطائفة: الوردانية غير مصنف: الوردانيات غير مصنف: ال...

 

14. Etappe der Vuelta a España 2023 AllgemeinesEtappe14. Etappe، Vuelta a España 2023Streckentyp HochgebirgsetappeDatum9. September 2023Etappenlänge156,2 kmAustragungsländer Frankreich SpanienStartSauveterre-de-BéarnZielLarra-BelaguaFahrer am Start156Fahrer am Ziel155Durchschnitts­geschwindigkeit36,95 km/hHöhenmeter4.655 mErgebnis1. Remco Evenepoel4 h 13 min 38 s(Soudal Quick-Step)2. Romain Bardet+ 1 min 12 s3. Lennert Van Eetvelt+ 6 min 33 s Remco Evenepoel(Soudal Quick-Step)Stand in...

 

Island and census-designated place in Washington, US A view of McNeil Island and the Puget Sound from Steilacoom, Washington The old Anderson Island School Anderson Island is the southernmost island in Puget Sound and a census-designated place of Pierce County, Washington, United States. It is accessible by boat or a 20-minute ferry ride from Steilacoom. Anderson Island is just south of McNeil Island. To the northwest, Key Peninsula is across Drayton Passage. The south basin of Puget Sound se...

Subfamily of bees Nomiinae Dieunomia heteropoda Scientific classification Domain: Eukaryota Kingdom: Animalia Phylum: Arthropoda Class: Insecta Order: Hymenoptera Family: Halictidae Subfamily: Nomiinae Nomiinae is a subfamily of sweat bees in the family Halictidae. There are about 11 genera and at least 550 described species in Nomiinae.[1][2] Nomia universitatis Genera These 11 genera belong to the subfamily Nomiinae: Dieunomia Cockerell, 1899 i c g b Halictonomia Pauly, 1980...

 

Thai dessertThapthim kropThapthim kropTypeDessertPlace of originThailandMain ingredientsWater chestnut, Coconut milk  Media: Thapthim krop Thapthim krop (Thai: ทับทิมกรอบ, pronounced [tʰáp.tʰīm krɔ̀ːp]; literally 'crispy rubies') is one of the best known Thai desserts, having been named one of the world's best 50 desserts by CNN Travel.[1] It is made of cubes of water chestnuts soaked in grenadine or red food dye, then boiled in tapioca flou...

 

Japanese toy line and television series Not to be confused with Dinosaur. This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Dinozaurs – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (March 2018) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) DinoZone / DinoZaursLogo for the English versionダイノゾー...

Danau Beruang Besar Sahtúcode: den is deprecated   (Slave) Great Bear Lakecode: en is deprecated   (Inggris) Grand lac de l'Ourscode: fr is deprecated   (Prancis) Danau Beruang Besar, Wilayah Barat LautLetakWilayah Barat LautKoordinat66°N 121°W / 66°N 121°W / 66; -121Koordinat: 66°N 121°W / 66°N 121°W / 66; -121Aliran keluar utamaSungai Beruang BesarWilayah tangkapan air114.717 km2 (44.292 sq ...

 

This article needs additional citations for verification. Please help improve this article by adding citations to reliable sources. Unsourced material may be challenged and removed.Find sources: Barhatta Upazila – news · newspapers · books · scholar · JSTOR (October 2020) (Learn how and when to remove this template message) Upazila in Mymensingh, BangladeshBarhatta বারহাট্টাUpazilaCoordinates: 24°54′N 90°52.5′E / ...

 

2006 Bexley Council election ← 2002 4 May 2006 2010 → All 63 seats to Bexley London Borough Council32 seats needed for a majority   First party Second party   Party Conservative Labour Seats won 54 9 Seat change 24 23 Popular vote 37,564 18,539 Percentage 50.0% 24.7% Swing 8.4% 8.3% Map of the results of the 2006 Bexley council election. Conservatives in blue and Labour in red. Council control before election Labour Council control after election...

For other people with the same name, see John Dunn (disambiguation). John Dunn (ca. 1764–1820) was a noted pipemaker, or maker of bagpipes. Born in Newcastle upon Tyne, England, Dunn was a cabinet maker by profession, initially a junior partner with George Brummell.[1] In the trade directories, he also appears in his own right as a turner (Whitehead 1790) and a plumb maker and turner (Mackenzie & Dent 1811). His address was Bell's Court, off Pilgrim Street. He was buried on 6 Fe...

 

For other places with the same name, see Leninsky District. District in Moscow Oblast, RussiaLeninsky District Ленинский районDistrict FlagCoat of armsLocation of Leninsky District in Moscow OblastCoordinates: 55°33′N 37°42′E / 55.550°N 37.700°E / 55.550; 37.700CountryRussiaFederal subjectMoscow Oblast[1]Administrative centerVidnoye[1]Area[2] • Total202.83 km2 (78.31 sq mi)Population (2010 Ce...

 

Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!