Optimum currency area

In economics, an optimum currency area (OCA) or optimal currency region (OCR) is a geographical region in which it would maximize economic efficiency to have the entire region share a single currency.

The underlying theory describes the optimal characteristics for the merger of currencies or the creation of a new currency. The theory is used often to argue whether or not a certain region is ready to become a currency union, one of the final stages in economic integration.

An optimal currency area is often larger than a country. For instance, part of the rationale behind the creation of the euro is that the individual countries of Europe do not each form an optimal currency area, but that Europe as a whole does.[1] The creation of the euro is often cited because it provides the most modern and largest-scale case study of an attempt to identify an optimum currency area, and provides a comparative before-and-after model by which to test the principles of the theory.

In theory, an optimal currency area could also be smaller than a country. Some economists have argued that the United States, for example, has some regions that do not fit into an optimal currency area with the rest of the country.[2]

The theory of the optimal currency area was pioneered in the 1960s by economist Robert Mundell.[3][4] Credit often goes to Mundell as the originator of the idea, but others point to earlier work done in the area by Abba Lerner.[5] Kenen (1969) and McKinnon (1963) were further developers of this idea.

Models

Optimum currency area with stationary expectations

Published by Mundell in 1961,[3] this is the most cited by economists. Here asymmetric shocks are considered to undermine the real economy, so if they are too important and cannot be controlled, a regime with floating exchange rates is considered better, because the global monetary policy (interest rates) will not be fine tuned for the particular situation of each constituent region.

The four often cited criteria for a successful currency union are:[6]

  • Labor mobility across the region. What if we suppose instead that Home and Foreign have an integrated labor market, so that labor is free to move between them: What effect will this have on the decision to form an optimum currency area? This includes physical ability to travel (visas, workers' rights, etc.), lack of cultural barriers to free movement (such as different languages) and institutional arrangements (such as the ability to have pensions transferred throughout the region).[3] For example, suppose Home and Foreign initially have equal output and unemployment. Suppose further that a negative shock hits Home, but not Foreign. If output falls and unemployment rises in Home, then labor will start to migrate to Foreign, where unemployment is lower. If this migration can occur with ease, the impact of the negative shock on Home will be less painful. Furthermore, there will be less need for Home to implement an independent monetary policy response for stabilization purposes. With an excess supply of labor in one region, adjustment can occur through migration.[7]
  • Openness with capital mobility and price and wage flexibility across the region. This is so that the market forces of supply and demand automatically distribute money and goods to where they are needed. In practice this does not work perfectly as there is no true wage flexibility.[8] The Eurozone members trade heavily with each other (intra-European trade is greater than international trade), and early (2006) empirical analyses of the 'euro effect' suggested that the single currency had already increased trade by 5 to 15 percent in the euro-zone when compared to trade between non-euro countries.[9]
  • A risk sharing system such as an automatic fiscal transfer mechanism to redistribute money to areas/sectors which have been adversely affected by the first two characteristics. This usually takes the form of taxation redistribution to less developed areas of a country/region. This policy, though theoretically accepted, is politically difficult to implement as the better-off regions rarely give up their revenue easily. Theoretically, Europe has a no-bailout clause in the Stability and Growth Pact, meaning that fiscal transfers are not allowed. During the 2010 Eurozone crisis (relating to government debt), the no-bailout clause was de facto abandoned in April 2010.[10] Subsequent theoretical analysis suggests that this was always an unrealistic expectation.[11] Federations and decentralized countries typically give subsidies to poorer regional governments (e.g. equalization payments in Canada).
  • Participant countries have similar business cycles. When one country experiences a boom or recession, other countries in the union are likely to follow. This allows the shared central bank to promote growth in downturns and to contain inflation in booms. Should countries in a currency union have idiosyncratic business cycles, then optimal monetary policy may diverge and union participants may be made worse off under a joint central bank.

Additional criteria suggested are:[12]

  • Production diversification (Peter Kenen)
  • Homogeneous preferences
  • Commonality of destiny ("Solidarity")

Optimum currency area with international risk sharing

Here Mundell tries to model how exchange rate uncertainty will interfere with the economy; this model is less often cited.

Supposing that the currency is managed properly, the larger the area, the better. In contrast with the previous model, asymmetric shocks are not considered to undermine the common currency because of the existence of the common currency. This spreads the shocks in the area because all regions share claims on each other in the same currency and can use them for dampening the shock, while in a flexible exchange rate regime, the cost will be concentrated on the individual regions, since the devaluation will reduce its buying power. So despite a less fine tuned monetary policy the real economy should do better.

A harvest failure, strikes, or war, in one of the countries causes a loss of real income, but the use of a common currency (or foreign exchange reserves) allows the country to run down its currency holdings and cushion the impact of the loss, drawing on the resources of the other country until the cost of the adjustment has been efficiently spread over the future. If, on the other hand, the two countries use separate monies with flexible exchange rates, the whole loss has to be borne alone; the common currency cannot serve as a shock absorber for the nation as a whole except insofar as the dumping of inconvertible currencies on foreign markets attracts a speculative capital inflow in favor of the depreciating currency.

— Mundell, 1973, Uncommon Arguments for Common Currencies p. 115

Mundell's work can be cited on both sides of the debate about the euro. However, in 1973 Mundell himself constructed an argument on the basis of the second model that was more favorable to the concept of a (then-hypothetical) shared European currency.

Rather than moving toward more flexibility in exchange rates within Europe the economic arguments suggest less flexibility and a closer integration of capital markets. These economic arguments are supported by social arguments as well. On every occasion when a social disturbance leads to the threat of a strike, and the strike to an increase in wages unjustified by increases in productivity and thence to devaluation, the national currency becomes threatened. Long-run costs for the nation as a whole are bartered away by governments for what they presume to be short-run political benefits. If instead, the European currencies were bound together disturbances in the country would be cushioned, with the shock weakened by capital movements.

— Robert Mundell, 1973, A Plan for a European Currency pp. 147 and 150

Applications

Canada

A review of the literature published for the Bank of Canada in 1999 cited dozens of studies on various aspects of OCA theory with special attention to whether Canada and the United States could form one. It made no conclusion on the topic.[13] Likewise, a 1999 report for the Parliamentary Research Branch discussed the pros and cons of Canada adopting the American dollar. While it made no judgment on the long term political desirability of a monetary union between Canada and the United States, it stated flatly that, at that time, Canada and the United did not share the free movement of labor and capital nor a common business cycle (Canada's being tied to resource prices) and thus did not satisfy OCA theory.[14]

A 2016 paper argued that Canada itself worked well as a currency area for all provinces except Alberta, which could benefit from having a separate currency.[15]

European Union

Europe exemplifies a situation unfavourable to a common currency. It is composed of separate nations, speaking different languages, with different customs, and having citizens feeling far greater loyalty and attachment to their own country than to a common market or to the idea of Europe.

There is never complete labour mobility, even within single countries. How much is enough? My answer was that the advantages of a common currency in terms of information and transactions costs, etc., have to be enough to overcome any disadvantages arising from insufficient labour mobility. I argue that the gains from a common currency in Europe have been and are sufficient in the case of Europe.

OCA theory has been most frequently applied to discussions of the euro and the European Union.[18] Many have argued that the EU did not actually meet the criteria for an OCA at the time the euro was adopted, and attribute the Eurozone's economic difficulties in part to continued failure to do so.[19][20] Europe does indeed score well on some of the measures characterising an OCA (such as symmetry of shocks). Poloz (1990) concluded that a European Monetary Union should be viable since the variability of real exchange rates in Europe was similar to that between Canadian regions.This work was cited by the European Commission itself in the 1990 report One Market, One Money.[21] By looking at the correlation of a region's GDP growth rate with that of the entire zone, the Eurozone countries show slightly greater correlations compared to the U.S. states. However, it has lower labour mobility than the United States, possibly due to language and cultural differences. In O'Rourke's paper, more than 40% of U.S. residents were born outside the state in which they live. In the Eurozone, only 14% people were born in a different country than the one in which they live. In fact, the U.S. economy was approaching a single labor market in the nineteenth century. However, for most parts of the Eurozone, such levels of labour mobility and labor market integration remain a distant prospect.[22] Furthermore, the U.S. economy, with a central federal fiscal authority, has stabilization transfers. When a state in the U.S. is in recession, every $1 drop in that state’s GDP would have an offsetting transfer of 28 cents.[22] Such stabilizing transfers are not present in both the Eurozone and EU; thus, they cannot rely on fiscal federalism to smooth out regional economic disturbances. The European crisis, however, may be pushing the EU towards more federal powers in fiscal policy.[23][24]

United States

Michael Kouparitsas (Chicago Fed) considered the United States as divided into the eight regions of the Bureau of Economic Analysis,[a] (Far West, Rocky Mountain, Plains, Great Lakes, Mideast, New England, Southwest, and Southeast). By developing a statistical model, he found that five of the eight regions of the country satisfied Mundell's criteria to form a single Optimal Currency Area. However, he found the fit of the Southeast and Southwest to be questionable. He also found that the Plains would not fit into an optimal currency area.[2]

Criticism

Keynesian

The notion of a currency that does not accord with a state, specifically one larger than a state – formally, of an international monetary authority without a corresponding fiscal authority – has been criticized by Keynesian and Post-Keynesian economists,[citation needed] who emphasize the role of deficit spending by a government (formally, fiscal authority) in the running of an economy, and consider using an international currency without fiscal authority to be a loss of "monetary sovereignty".

Specifically, Keynesian economists[which?] argue that fiscal stimulus in the form of deficit spending is the most powerful method of fighting unemployment during a liquidity trap.[citation needed] Such stimulus may not be possible if states in a monetary union are not allowed to run sufficient deficits.

The Post-Keynesian theory of Neo-Chartalism holds that government deficit spending creates money, that ability to print money is fundamental to a state's ability to command resources, and that "money and monetary policy are intricately linked to political sovereignty and fiscal authority".[25] Both of these critiques consider the transactional benefits of a shared currency to be minor compared to these drawbacks, and more generally place less emphasis on the transactional function of money (a medium of exchange) and greater emphasis on its use as a unit of account.

Self-fulfilling argument

In Mundell’s first model, countries regard all of the conditions as given, and assuming they have adequate information, they can then judge whether the costs of forming a currency union outweigh the benefits. However, another school of thought[which?] argues[where?] that some of the OCA criteria are not given and fixed, but rather they are economic outcomes (i.e., endogenous) determined by the creation of the currency union itself.[citation needed]

Consider goods market interaction as an example: if the OCA criteria were applied before the currency union forms, then many countries might exhibit low trade volumes and low market integration; which means that OCA criteria are not met. Thus, the currency union might not be formed based on those current characteristics. However, if the currency union was established anyway, its member-states would trade so much more that, in the end, the OCA criteria would be met. This logic suggests that the OCA criteria can be self-fulfilling. Furthermore, greater integration under the OCA project might also improve other OCA criteria. For example, if goods markets are better connected, shocks will be more rapidly transmitted within the OCA and will be felt more symmetrically.

However, caution should be employed when analysing the self-fulfilling argument. Firstly, the self-fulfilling effect's impact may not be significant. According to a recent study by Richard Baldwin, a trade economist at the Graduate Institute of International Studies in Geneva, the boost to trade within the Eurozone from the single currency is much smaller: between 5% and 15%, with a best estimate of 9%.[26]

The second counter-argument[by whom?] is that further goods market integration might also lead to more specialization in production. Once individual firms can easily serve the whole OCA market, and not just their national market, they will exploit economies of scale and concentrate production. Some sectors in the OCA might end up becoming concentrated in a few locations. The United States is a good example: financial services are centered in New York City, entertainment in Los Angeles, and technology in Silicon Valley. If specialization increases, each country will be less diversified and will face more asymmetric shocks; weakening the case for the self-fulfilling OCA argument.[7]

See also

Notes

  1. ^ For map see U.S. Bureau of Economic Analysis Regions (Iowa State University Iowa Community Indicators Program)

References

  1. ^ Baldwin, Richard; Wyplosz, Charles (2004). The Economics of European Integration. New York: McGraw Hill. ISBN 978-0-07-710394-1. [page needed]
  2. ^ a b Kouparitsas, Michael A. (2001). "Is the United States an optimum currency area? An empirical analysis of regional business cycles" (PDF). Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago Working Paper. 2001–21.
  3. ^ a b c Mundell, R. A. (1961). "A Theory of Optimum Currency Areas". American Economic Review. 51 (4): 657–665. JSTOR 1812792.
  4. ^ Coy, Peter (October 25, 1999). "Why Mundell Won the Nobel: For work that led to the euro, not for his supply-side theory". BusinessWeek. Archived from the original on April 14, 2001.
  5. ^ Scitovsky, Tibor (1984). "Lerner's Contribution to Economics". Journal of Economic Literature. 22 (4): 1547–1571 [see pp. 1555–6 for discussion of OCA]. JSTOR 2725381.
  6. ^ Frankel, Jeffrey A. & Rose, Andrew K. (1997). "The Endogenity of the Optimum Currency Area Criteria" (PDF). The Economic Journal. 108 (449): 1009–1025. doi:10.1111/1468-0297.00327. S2CID 8708168.
  7. ^ a b Feenstra, Robert C., and Alan M. Taylor. "Chapter 10." International Macroeconomics. New York: Worth, 2014. 412-14. Print.
  8. ^ McKinnon, R. I. (1988). "Monetary and Exchange Rate Policies for International Financial Stability: A Proposal". The Journal of Economic Perspectives. 2 (1): 83–103. doi:10.1257/jep.2.1.83. JSTOR 1942741.
  9. ^ Baldwin, Richard (2006). In or Out: Does it Matter? An Evidence-Based Analysis of the Euro's Trade Effects. London: Centre for Economic Policy Research. ISBN 978-1-898128-91-5.
  10. ^ "Greece Takes Bailout, but Doubts for Region Persist". New York Times. May 3, 2010.
  11. ^ The Trilemma of a Monetary Union: Another Impossible Trinity Hanno Beck, Aloys Prinz, Intereconomics Review of European Economic Policy, Volume 47, January/February 2012, Number 1 · pp. 39-43. "A monetary union among autonomous countries cannot simultaneously maintain an independent monetary policy, national fiscal sovereignty and a no-bailout clause. These three features make up an impossible trinity, and attempts to preserve all three concurrently will ultimately end in failure. In order to save EMU, one of these three must be abandoned."
  12. ^ van Marrewijk, Charles; Ottens, Daniël; Schueller, Stephan (2006). International economics: theory, application, and policy. Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. p. 620. ISBN 978-0-19-928098-8.
  13. ^ Lafrance, Robert; St-Amant, Pierre. Optimal Currency Areas: A Review of the Recent Literature. Bank of Canada.
  14. ^ "The Pros and Cons of a Monetary Union with the U.S. (PRB 99-9E)". publications.gc.ca. Retrieved 2023-01-05.
  15. ^ Chaban, Maxym; Voss, Graham M. (May 2016). "Is Canada an optimal currency area? An inflation targeting perspective". Canadian Journal of Economics. 49 (2): 738–771. doi:10.1111/caje.12212. ISSN 0008-4085. S2CID 150867784.
  16. ^ The Times, London, November 19, 1997
  17. ^ Robert Mundell: Euro is here to stay, Financial Post, June 8, 2012
  18. ^ Irena Vrnáková & Hana Bartušková, 2013. "Is Euro Area an Optimal Currency Area and What Barriers Could Obstruct Its Future Development?," ACTA VSFS, University of Finance and Administration, vol. 7(2), pages 123-144.
  19. ^ Ricci, Luca A. (March 2008). "A model of an optimum currency area". Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment e-Journal. 2 (8): 1–31. doi:10.5018/economics-ejournal.ja.2008-8. hdl:10419/17968.
  20. ^ Krugman, Paul (19 July 2015). "The Euroskeptic Vindication (blog)". Paul Krugman. Retrieved 24 July 2015.
  21. ^ "One market, one money: An evaluation of the potential benefits and costs of forming an economic and monetary union" (PDF). European Economy. Directorate-General for Economic and Financial Affairs.{{cite journal}}: CS1 maint: others (link)
  22. ^ a b O’Rourke, Kevin (Summer 2013). "Cross of Euros". Journal of Economic Perspectives. 27 (3): 167–192. doi:10.1257/jep.27.3.167.
  23. ^ Caporaso, James A.; Kim, Min–hyung; Durrett, Warren N.; Wesley, Richard B. (August 2015). "Still a regulatory state? The European Union and the financial crisis". Journal of European Public Policy. 22 (7): 889–907. doi:10.1080/13501763.2014.988638. S2CID 153684746.
  24. ^ Beck, Hanno; Prinz, Aloys (January 2012). "The Trilemma of a Monetary Union: Another Impossible Trinity". INTERECONOMICS Review of European Economic Policy. 47 (1): 39–43. doi:10.1007/s10272-012-0404-0. hdl:10419/98237. S2CID 154652344.
  25. ^ Goodhart, Charles A.E. (August 1998). "The two concepts of money: implications for the analysis of optimal currency areas". European Journal of Political Economy. 14 (3): 407–432. doi:10.1016/S0176-2680(98)00015-9. Pdf.
    See also: Wray, L. Randall (July 2000). "The Neo-Chartalist Approach to Money" (Working Paper No. 10). Center for Full Employment and Price Stability. {{cite journal}}: Cite journal requires |journal= (help)
  26. ^ Baldwin, Richard E. (2006). In Or Out: Does it Matter? : an Evidence-based Analysis of the Euro's Trade Effects. Centre for Economic Policy Research. ISBN 978-1-898128-91-5.

Read other articles:

Tatiana de Liechtenstein Princesa de LiechtensteinInformación personalNombre completo Tatiana Nora María de Liechtenstein (en alemán: Tatjana Nora Maria von und zu Liechtenstein)Otros títulos Condesa de Rietberg(1973 - actual) Baronesa consorte de Lattorff(1999 - actual)Nacimiento 10 de abril de 1973 (50 años)San Galo, SuizaReligión CatólicaFamiliaCasa real Casa de LiechtensteinDinastía Casa de Lattorff (por matrimonio)Padre Juan Adán IIMadre Condesa María Kinsky de Wchinitz y ...

 

Герберт Веллс (1866—1946) перед 1922 р. Ге́рберт Джордж Ве́ллс був плідним письменником художніх та науково-популярних творів. Його письменницька кар'єра охоплює більше шістдесяти років, за ранні романи наукової фантастики його називають (поряд з Жулем Верном і Г'юго Гернсбе

 

هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (أبريل 2019) غابرييلا فيري   معلومات شخصية الميلاد 18 سبتمبر 1942  روما  الوفاة 3 أبريل 2004 (61 سنة)   كورتشيانو  سبب الوفاة سقوط  مكان الدفن مقبرة كامبو فيرانو ...

PICK MELagu oleh PRODUCE 101DirilisDecember 17, 2015FormatDigital downloadDirekam2015GenreK-pop, dance-pop, electropop, EDMDurasi3:46LabelCJ E&MPenciptaMidas-TProduserDJ KOO, MaximiteVideo musikPick Me di YouTube Pick Me adalah lagu yang dirilis oleh program survival Korea Selatan PRODUCE 101. Lagu ini dirilis secara online sebagai singel digital pada 17 Desember 2015 melalui CJ E&M. Perilisan Produce 101 merilis lagu Pick Me pada 17 Desember, bersama dengan musik video. Pick Me adala...

 

هذه المقالة يتيمة إذ تصل إليها مقالات أخرى قليلة جدًا. فضلًا، ساعد بإضافة وصلة إليها في مقالات متعلقة بها. (يوليو 2023) مجمع سليمان الضراط للألعاب الرياضيةمعلومات عامةالمنطقة الإدارية بنغازي البلد  ليبيا الاستعمالالمالك الاتحاد الليبي لكرة السلةالموقع الجغرافيالإحداثي...

 

Карім Джамар Особисті дані Повне ім'я Карім Джамар (Kareem Jamar)Дата народження 16 жовтня 1992 (31 рік)(19921016)Місце народження Лос-Анджелес, КаліфорніяКраїна  США Зріст 196 см Вага 95 кг Інформація про клуби Поточний клуб «Харківські Соколи» Номер 32 Позиція Атакуваль

الاحتجاجات الصّينيّة المطالبة بالدّيمقراطيّة 2011م الاحتجاجات الصينية المطالبة بالديمقراطية 2011 [1] إشارة إلى تحركات الشارع الصيني الأسبوعية في أكثر من اثني عشر مدينة في بر الصين الرئيسى اعتبارا من يوم 20 فبراير 2011، والمستوحاة من الاسم الذي أطلق على ثورة الياسمين التونس...

 

Ця стаття потребує додаткових посилань на джерела для поліпшення її перевірності. Будь ласка, допоможіть удосконалити цю статтю, додавши посилання на надійні (авторитетні) джерела. Зверніться на сторінку обговорення за поясненнями та допоможіть виправити недоліки. Мат...

 

Carl Friedrich Hermann RoeslerCarl Friedrich Hermann RoeslerBornDecember 18, 1834Lauf an der Pegnitz, German ConfederationDiedDecember 2, 1894(1894-12-02) (aged 59)Bolzano, Austria-HungaryNationalityGermanOther namesHermann RoeslerOccupation(s)legal scholar, economist, foreign advisor to JapanKnown forForeign advisor to Meiji Japan Carl Friedrich Hermann Roesler (18 December 1834 – 2 December 1894) was a German legal scholar, economist, and foreign advisor to the Meiji pe...

Parliamentary constituency in the United Kingdom, 1885–1983 Houghton-le-SpringFormer County constituencyfor the House of CommonsBoundary of Houghton-le-Spring in County Durham, boundaries 1974-83CountyCounty DurhamMajor settlementsHoughton-le-Spring1885–1983SeatsOneCreated fromSouth DurhamReplaced byHoughton & Washington and Easington[1] Houghton-le-Spring was a county constituency of the House of Commons of the Parliament of the United Kingdom from 1885 to 1983. Centred on th...

 

一般県道 鹿児島県道365号 脇本赤瀬川線一般県道 脇本赤瀬川線 起点 鹿児島県阿久根市脇本【北緯32度5分29.9秒 東経130度11分27.5秒 / 北緯32.091639度 東経130.190972度 / 32.091639; 130.190972 (県道365号起点)】 終点 鹿児島県阿久根市赤瀬川【北緯32度1分50.4秒 東経130度12分1.4秒 / 北緯32.030667度 東経130.200389度 / 32.030667; 130.200389 (県道365号終...

 

Artikel ini perlu dikembangkan agar dapat memenuhi kriteria sebagai entri Wikipedia.Bantulah untuk mengembangkan artikel ini. Jika tidak dikembangkan, artikel ini akan dihapus. 301 BavariaPenemuanDitemukan olehJohann PalisaTanggal penemuan16 November 1890PenamaanAsal namaBavariaKategori planet minorSabuk utama (Keluarga Liberatrix)Ciri-ciri orbitEpos 30 Januari 2005 (Hari Julian 2453400.5)Aphelion434.654 Gm (2.905 SA)Perihelion381.098 Gm (2.547 SA)Sumbu semimayor407.876 Gm (2.7...

Дмитрий Петрович Боенко Дата рождения 1918 Место рождения село Комаровка, Рыльский уезд, Курская губерния, РСФСР Дата смерти 20 октября 1943(1943-10-20) Место смерти Черкасская область, СССР Принадлежность  СССР Род войск пехота Годы службы 1939—1943 Звание Часть 23-й стр...

 

Mountain Longleaf National Wildlife RefugeIUCN category IV (habitat/species management area)Longleaf pine (Pinus palustris)Show map of the United StatesShow map of AlabamaLocationCalhoun County, Alabama, United StatesNearest cityAnniston, AlabamaCoordinates33°41′49″N 85°45′07″W / 33.696851°N 85.751896°W / 33.696851; -85.751896Area9,015.68 acres (36 km2)[1]Established2003Governing bodyU.S. Fish and Wildlife ServiceWebsiteMountain Longl...

 

Forgery of an ancient Egyptian statue The Amarna Princess The Amarna Princess, sometimes referred to as the Bolton Amarna Princess, is a statue forged by British art forger Shaun Greenhalgh and sold by his father George Sr. to Bolton Museum for £440,000 in 2003.[1] Based on the Amarna art-style of ancient Egypt, the purchase of the Amarna Princess was feted as a coup by the museum and it remained on display for three years.[2] However, in November 2005, Greenhalgh was brought...

This article is part of a series on theCulture of the Philippines Society History Language sign language People ethnic groups indigenous peoples Religion Value system Kinship Honorifics Arts and literature Architecture Arts Comics Dance Fashion and clothing Literature Music Other Cuisine Cultural Properties Folklore Historical markers Media newspapers radio cinema TV Internet Mythology Public holidays festivals Sports Symbols Anthem Bird Coat of arms Flag Flower Gem Great Seal Language Motto ...

 

Marzano di Nolacomune Marzano di Nola – VedutaVesuvio visto dal Santuario di Marzano di Nola LocalizzazioneStato Italia Regione Campania Provincia Avellino AmministrazioneSindacoFrancesco Addeo (PSI) dal 10-6-2018 TerritorioCoordinate40°54′13″N 14°35′05″E / 40.903611°N 14.584722°E40.903611; 14.584722 (Marzano di Nola)Coordinate: 40°54′13″N 14°35′05″E / 40.903611°N 14.584722°E40.903611; 14.584722 (Marzano ...

 

You can help expand this article with text translated from the corresponding article in French. (March 2019) Click [show] for important translation instructions. View a machine-translated version of the French article. Machine translation, like DeepL or Google Translate, is a useful starting point for translations, but translators must revise errors as necessary and confirm that the translation is accurate, rather than simply copy-pasting machine-translated text into the English Wikipedi...

2002 film by Neil LaBute PossessionTheatrical release posterDirected byNeil LaButeWritten byDavid Henry HwangLaura JonesNeil LaButeBased onPossession: A Romance by A. S. ByattProduced byBarry LevinsonStephen PevnerPaula WeinsteinStarringAaron EckhartGwyneth PaltrowJeremy NorthamJennifer EhleLena HeadeyToby StephensCinematographyJean-Yves EscoffierEdited byClaire SimpsonMusic byGabriel YaredProductioncompanyBaltimore Spring Creek PicturesDistributed byFocus Features (United States)Warner Bros....

 

В Википедии есть статьи о других людях с такой фамилией, см. Васильчиков; Васильчиков, Илларион. Илларион Сергеевич Васильчиков Дата рождения 15 апреля 1881(1881-04-15) Место рождения Санкт-Петербург Дата смерти 3 июня 1969(1969-06-03) (88 лет) Место смерти Эберштайнбург[de], Баден-Баден, ФР...

 

Strategi Solo vs Squad di Free Fire: Cara Menang Mudah!